The Review of Economics and Statistics
VOL. CIII
JULY 2021
NUMBER 3
THE VIRTUOUS CYCLE OF PROPERTY
Marco Fabbri and Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci*
Abstract—This paper shows that formalizing private property rights has
a positive effect on the propensity to respect the property of others. 我们
study a recent large-scale land tenure reform in West Africa that was the
first of its kind to be implemented as a randomized control trial. Results of
a modified dictator game show that the formalization of private property
rights reduced an individual’s willingness to take from others’ endowment.
We used additional experimental measures and postexperimental survey
data to rule out alternative explanations for the observed behavior that do
not imply a change in preferences.
我.
介绍
WHILE there is mounting evidence of the importance of
property rights in economic growth and societal de-
发展 (Acemoglu, 约翰逊, & 罗宾逊, 2005; Mokyr,
2009; 北, 1991), the countours of the concept of property
vary, sometime sharply, across disciplines (Hare, Reeve, &
Blossey, 2016; 霍奇森, 2015; Merrill & 史密斯, 2001). 然而
a common denominator in any definition of property rights is
the notion of respect for the property of others, 那是, the idea
that under a system of property rights, an individual will—
spontaneously or out of fear of being punished—refrain from
interfering with another’s enjoyment of their own property.
Respect for property is considered a key determinant
of economic development because it increases the private
returns on entrepreneurship in societies where egalitarian
norms may act against individual wealth accumulation (Barr
Received for publication June 17, 2019. Revision accepted for publication
十二月 11, 2019. Editor: Shachar Kariv.
∗Fabbri: University Pompeu Fabra and Barcelona GSE; Dari-Mattiacci:
哥伦比亚大学.
We thank the editor, Shachar Kariv, and two anonymous referees for com-
ments and suggestions that greatly improved the quality of this paper. 我们是
grateful to the Behavioural Approach to Contract and Tort research program
at Erasmus University Rotterdam; the Innovation Program at the Erasmus
School of Law; and the Erasmus Trustfonds for generous financial sup-
港口. We are deeply indebted to Michael Faure for his support; this project
would have been not possible without him. A special thanks to Deo-Gracias
Houndolo for his amazing organizational skills and his support during the
fieldwork. We are also grateful to Benito Arrunãda, Christoph Engel, Jonah
Gelbach, Michael Heller, Jon Klick, Justin McCrary, Giacomo Ponzetto,
Matteo Rizzolli, Alexander Stremitzer, Alessandro Tarozzi, and partici-
pants at seminars and workshops at the Erasmus University Rotterdam, ETH
Zurich, 哈佛, University of Amsterdam, and University Pompeu Fabra
for many insightful comments. Calixte Adjallala, Kosmas Alofa, Baithatou
Amidou, Dossou Fiogbe, Gaston Gnonlonfoun, Rabitou Gounou, Idrissou
Soulé, Mohamed Sedou, Alou Sanni, Rosemonde Sohantode, and Israelia
Zannou provided excellent research assistance. 最后, we thank Malissa
Bales for her skilled editorial assistance. The usual disclaimer applies.
A supplemental appendix is available online at https://doi.org/10.1162/
rest_a_00905.
& 斯坦因, 2008; Bernard, De Janvry, & Sadoulet, 2010; Plat-
teau, 2000). 更普遍, respect for property fosters the
emergence and supports the functioning of a market econ-
奥米, and consequently spurs economic growth (Glaeser et al.,
2004).
The literature identifies three possible channels through
which respect for property is induced: first-, second-, 和
third-party enforcement. Starting from the last, third-party
enforcement institutions, such as a (formal) legal system or
(informal) sanctions triggered by social norms of behavior,
provide powerful incentives for would-be takers. Alterna-
主动地, possessors may invest in self-protection and display
aggressive defensive behavior against potential intruders, 遵循-
lowing a behavioral pattern that is common not only among
人类 (约翰逊 & Toft, 2014; Pape, 2003) but also in sev-
eral animal species (Kokko, 2013). Virtually any legal system
justifies reasonable self-defense of one’s own property and
various forms of self-help, thereby allowing direct, 第二-
party enforcement. 最后, a burgeoning literature investi-
gates behavior based on an intrinsic motivation to not appro-
priate another’s property. Social scientists report that such an
internalization mechanism—alternatively labeled first-party
enforcement or taking aversion—is at work in human soci-
道德的 (看, 例如, Bardsley, 2008; Cappelen et al., 2013; Krupka
& 韦伯, 2013; List, 2007; for a survey of the literature re-
porting evidence of first-party enforcement and a thorough
methodological discussion see Faillo, Rizzolli, & Tontrup,
2019).
As compared to the other two mechanisms described
多于, first-party enforcement yields specific efficiency
gains. 一方面, setting up and maintaining a formal
third-party enforcement system requires substantial invest-
ments in monitoring and sanctioning institutions, such as po-
lice and courts. Even in systems based on informal sanctions,
punishment is costly, might be suboptimally provided be-
cause of free-riding, and could give rise to arbitrariness, 迪斯-
定罪, and welfare-reducing social norms (Arruñada,
Zanarone, & Garoupa, 2018; Fabbri & Carbonara, 2017;
Grechenig, Nicklisch, & Thöni, 2010; Herrmann, Thöni, &
Gächter, 2008). 另一方面, second-party enforcement
presupposes costly precautions by the owner (Ayres & 莱维特,
1998; Heaton et al., 2016), as well as potential losses aris-
ing from conflicts between the owner and potential intruders,
which might (and often do) degenerate in devastating and
The Review of Economics and Statistics, 七月 2021, 103(3): 413–427
© 2020 由哈佛大学和麻省理工学院的校长和研究员撰写
https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00905
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
414
THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
long-lasting feuds with reciprocal retaliations (Bolle, Tan, &
Zizzo, 2014; Nikiforakis, 2008).
When driven by internalized norms of behavior, respect for
property frees up resources that owners would otherwise in-
vest in self-protection and saves the costs associated with for-
mal and informal punishment institutions. 由于这些原因,
scholars are paying increasing attention to the determinants
of first-party enforcement. Some authors claim that humans
are characterized by an innate sense of property (Sääksvuori
等人。, 2016; Zeki, Goodenough, & Stake, 2004). Others theo-
rize that respect for property results from the evolutionary and
societal forces that shaped our behavior over centuries (Gin-
tis, 2007; Eswaran & Neary, 2014). Despite these important
theoretical contributions, only a few recent papers empiri-
cally investigate the determinants of first-party enforcement.
尤其, Jakiela (2015) and Jakiela, Miguel, and Te Velde
(2015) show that educational attainments and market inte-
gration are important determinants of increased first-party
enforcement of respect for property rights on earned income.
Fabbri, Rizzolli, and Maruotti (2018) show that individuals
respect significantly more strongly the property of those who
acquired it through labor rather than luck or first possession,
which nicely aligns with Locke’s theory of property (亨利,
1999; 洛克, 2014, 1860). 然而, we are not aware of any
empirical study investigating the relationship between the
structure and organization of formal institutions and respect
for property.
Our study contributes some new pieces of this puzzle by es-
timating the causal effects of a major reform of property rights
on the social preferences governing an individual’s propen-
sity to appropriate others’ property, as captured in an eco-
nomic experiment. The reform, implemented by the govern-
ment of Benin with the support of the Millennium Challenge
Corporation and the World Bank between 2009 和 2011 和
whose details are provided in the next section, transformed
collective informal customary rights over land into formal
individual rights akin to private property. Estimating the uni-
variate causal effects of the reform on respect for property
faces an empirical challenge, since preferences and institu-
tions are endogenously codetermined variables that coevolve.
A way to overcome the identification problem consists of
using natural experiments to study the effects of institutional
shocks on preferences.1 In the context of policy and legal
改革, this approach has been criticized for potential endo-
geneity biases because the institutional change might actually
reflect the preferences of the institution builders rather than
represent an endogenous shock (Alesina & Giuliano, 2015).
A second set of studies uses laboratory experiments to solve
the identification problem.2 A concern with this approach
relates to the external validity of the results, because the in-
1Examples of (allegedly exogenous) institutional shocks used in previous
literature are political events (Alesina & Fuchs-Schündeln, 2007; Botticini
& Eckstein, 2007), changes in laws and regulations (Gruber & Hungerman,
2008), and modifications of state borders (Becker et al., 2016).
2The approach consists of observing the participants’ reactions to exoge-
nous manipulations of the institutional characteristics of the games played
stitutions manipulated in the lab bear little resemblance to
real-life property institutions and because of the small—and
often nonrepresentative—samples of participants (Henrich,
Heine, & Norenzayan, 2010; Loewenstein, 1999; Schram,
2005).
We attempt to overcome these problems by proposing an
innovative research design that combines laboratory experi-
ments with a unique case of institutional reform implemented
as a large-scale randomized control trial. Our identification
strategy is based on the peculiar process of implementation
that characterized the Beninese land rights reform: the vil-
lages in which the reform was implemented were randomly
selected from a pool of hundreds of Beninese villages. 我们
then collected data from a lab-in-the-field experiment de-
signed to measure respect for property in both selected and
nonselected villages. Compared to previous related studies,
our approach has the advantage of relying on a clean identi-
fication strategy while mitigating external validity concerns.
The laboratory setting in which we measure the effects of
experiencing the land tenure reform on the villagers’ respect
for property guarantees anonymity and silences the influence
of second- and third-party enforcement institutions, 还有
as other possible confounding factors. Economic experiments
are a widely used tool to elicit individual and social prefer-
恩塞斯 (Charness & Rabin, 2002; Croson & Gächter, 2010;
史密斯, 1994). Our experiment is based on a variant of the
traditional dictator game, in which a participant has the op-
portunity to take some or all of the resources from another
passive player’s endowment at no cost. The game is designed
to measure preferences affecting an individual’s willingness
to take others’ property. This modified dictator game has of-
ten been used in previous literature (看, 例如, Dreber et al.,
2013; Khadjavi, 2015; Korenok, Millner, & Razzolini, 2018;
Oxoby & Spraggon, 2008).
Results from our experiment show that participants who
experienced the land tenure reform appropriate significantly
less from others than those belonging to the control group.
Point estimates suggest a 40% 到 60% reduction in the share
of endowment that treated subjects take from others. 我们骗-
sider several alternatives to the explanation that experiencing
formal individual land rights directly alters social preferences
by increasing respect for the property of others. We tested
无论, in our sample, experiencing the land tenure reform
has affected subjects’ observed behavior via channels such
as wealth effects, investments in education, access to credit,
and likelihood to participate in financial activities. We report
evidence suggesting that none of these channels can explain
结果. 相似地, we show that neither the likelihood
to experience conflicts nor use formal versus customary in-
stitutions for conflict resolution differs between treated and
control villages, thus providing evidence against the possi-
bility that changes in these factors explain the observed be-
行为. We also report evidence that the reform did not affect
作为, 例如, in Bó, 促进, and Putterman (2010), Rodriguez-Sickert,
Guzmán, and Cárdenas (2008), Sutter, Haigner, and Kocher (2010).
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
THE VIRTUOUS CYCLE OF PROPERTY
415
participants’ level of altruism, beliefs about the level of oth-
ers’ altruism, or perception of distributional norms in the
社会, thus showing that our results cannot be explained
by changes in altruism or beliefs regarding the existing so-
cial norms. 最后, we show that our results cannot be ex-
plained by changes in other individual beliefs related to the
establishment of a market economy, such as individualism,
self-determination, or the importance of money.
From a methodological perspective, our work is directly
related to studies that have used the taking dictator game
in experiment conducted in low- and medium-income coun-
尝试 (Barr et al., 2015; Jakiela, 2011). The paper is also re-
lated to the literature that employs laboratory experiments
to evaluate the impact of development interventions (Ban,
Gilligan, & Rieger, 2015; Fabbri, 2018; Jakiela, 2014; Lucas
等人。, 2014; Paluck & 绿色的, 2009). 相似地, we contribute
to a branch of the literature that uses laboratory games to
compare the behavior of subjects living in different insti-
tutional settings (Bigoni et al., 2016; Henrich et al., 2001;
Herrmann et al., 2008). 最后, we contribute to recent
studies that combine natural experiments to determine
to treatment with laboratory experiments to
assignment
elicit participants’ preferences (Fisman et al., 2015; Gneezy,
Leibbrandt, & List, 2016; Voors et al., 2012).
The paper is structured as follows. In the section II, 我们
describe the institutional framework in which the study takes
地方. Section III presents the experimental design and pro-
cedure, and section IV reports the results obtained. 部分
V discusses whether the empirical evidence supports possi-
ble alternative explanations to the hypothesis that the reform
increased individual preferences for respect for property. 秒-
tion VI concludes.
二.
Institutional Framework
While systems of formal land ownership registration have
been introduced in virtually every African state, customary
land rights still represent the predominant land tenure ar-
rangement in most rural areas, including Benin. Customary
land rights are characterized by a complex set of principles
and regulations that are typically defined at the village or lo-
cal level. While customary arrangements vary widely, 他们
have a number of key features in common (Delville, 2006).
Customary rights consist of a set of socially determined
land-use rules, where access to land is an integral part of
the structure of society and tenure is determined by socio-
political and family relationships. Governance and enforce-
ment are left to local authorities, such as village elders,
religious authorities, and local political leaders, who arbi-
trate cases based on previous occupancy or religious norms
(Delville, 2006).
This system implies that rights held by individuals are the
result of a social and political process of negotiations over-
seen by customary authorities. This enforcement process has
an inherently procedural nature. Rules governing customary
arrangements do not provide a precise codification of each
landholder’s rights; 反而, they only define procedures by
which an individual obtains access to the land (Chauveau,
Bosc, & Pescay, 1996). 所以, the informal nature of cus-
tomary rules prevents upfront the possibility of establishing
a set of well-defined land property rights.
Population growth and the resulting increased pressure on
natural resources pose serious concerns for the functioning
of informal customary arrangements. Scholars notice that the
absence of written documentation regarding land use con-
tributes to an increase in conflicts over inheritance rights and
land use (Deininger & Castagnini, 2006). In Benin, the pol-
icy response to problems resulting from tenure insecurity has
been a land tenure reform known as the Plan Foncier Rural
(PFR), which was enacted in the 1980s and whose imple-
mentation we document in this paper. The reform consists of
socio-land surveys at the village level to identify righthold-
呃, their rights, and parcel boundaries. Rights and associated
rightholders are then recorded in public registries, and a pro-
cess of land demarcation takes place. The process allows for
public objection to the proposed registration of rights and re-
quires that rightholders and neighbors publicly sign survey
记录. Registered plots acquire a new legal status, 奖
presumption of ownership recognized by courts, and can be
transformed into land titles following a simplified procedure.
而且, registered rights enjoy legal protection from the
formal judicial system and make it possible to sell or use reg-
istered plots as collateral. Given these characteristics, 甚至
if the registration of rights does not directly confer legal title
over the plot, the PFR awards rights that are de facto akin to
private property.3 Therefore, the PFR injected a major change
into the institutional contours of property rights over land,
which is particularly important because land is the only asset
of most rural villagers (Goldstein et al., 2016).
Benin started experimenting with a pilot implementation
of the PFR in 1993. 然而, due to lack of resources, 这
reform interested only a small number of villages until 2006,
when the Millennium Change Account subsidized a five-year
PFR implementation program under the auspices of the World
Bank. The key characteristic of the Beninese PFR is that
implementation followed a randomized control trial process
involving hundreds of rural villages. 实际上, this is the first
3From a purely legal perspective, our use of the term “private property”
is somewhat imprecise because, according to Beninese law, only formal
land titles confer private property rights. In the initial plan for the reform
implementation, the Rural Land Act 2007-003 introduced the Certificat
Fonciers, land certificates recording rights registered during PFR that the
Beninese administrative authority would release automatically to individual
rightholders. The certificates could then be converted into land ownership
titles (Titre Foncier) following a specific procedure. The release of PFR
certificates was muted by Rural Land Law 2013-001, “Land and Prop-
erty Code.” The new law incorporated the Certificat Foncier into the Titre
Foncier and further confirmed the importance of registered customary rights
by giving them legal recognition and establishing a simplified procedure
for their upgrade to formal legal titles on land. In the text, we use the term
“private property” because, with the caveats illustrated above, land rights
registered during the PFR share the key features characterizing a system of
well-defined private property rights: exclusive use, transferability, 和
possibility to use the land as collateral.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
416
THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
case of a large-scale land tenure reform implemented as a
randomized control trial.
The objective of the reform was to deliver land certificates
在 300 rural villages across forty communes.4 In the pre-
liminary phase of the project, interested rural villages in the
communes were informed about the PFR reform and were
invited to apply in order to participate in the lottery. As a sec-
ond step, each application received was examined to verify
whether the village met certain eligibility criteria.5 Among
这 1,235 villages that applied for participating in the PFR
lottery, 576 were judged eligible.
A subsample of 300 villages was selected via public lot-
tery among the eligible villages. 最后, in the pe-
里约德 2009 到 2011, the Beninese government supported by
the Millennium Challenge Corporation and the World Bank
implemented the PFR in these selected villages (the treated
团体).6 The remaining 276 nonselected villages (the control
团体) did not receive any intervention and, as of today, 骗局-
tinue to have customary land rights. 数字 1 shows a map of
communes and villages interested by PFR.
三、.
The Experiment
A.
Game Design
We implement a modified dictator game, in which the par-
ticipant, acting in the role of dictator, has the ability to ap-
propriate resources from an anonymous passive player’s en-
dowment. Participants are matched in pairs and randomly
assigned to the role of dictator or passive player. The passive
player receives from the experimenter 10 coins. Each coin is
worth XOF 100 (大约 $0.17).7 The dictator initially has zero coins. 然而, the dictator has the opportunity to take some or all the coins from the passive player at no cost. To limit experimenter demand effects, we followed an ex- perimental procedure that makes the participants’ decisions blind to the experimenter onsite.8 Once in the decision room, the dictator is presented with two envelopes, one yellow and one brown, marked by an identification number. In the yellow envelope are the 10 coins owned by the passive player; the brown envelope is empty. The dictator is instructed that the 10 coins in the yellow envelope are property of the passive 4Communes are institutional units similar to counties. Benin has 77 com- munes. The communes that were excluded from the opportunity to partici- pate in the PFR lottery are those where nongovernmental organizations and other organizations were engaging in other programs of land governance at the time of the PFR design. 5The criteria for eligibility were poverty index, potential for commercial activities, regional market integration, local interest in promoting gender equality, infrastructure for economic activities, compliance with the PFR application procedure, incidence of land conflicts, and the production of main crops. 6Since four selected villages refused to complete the program implemen- 站, the treated sample is composed of 296 villages. 7The average weekly income for an household in our sample is around XOF 12,000. 8而且, the experimenter on site and the research assistants did not know whether they were operating in a treated or control village. FIGURE 1.—COMMUNES AND VILLAGES IN THE PLAN FONCIER RURAL IN THE LOTTERY POOL AND GEOGRAPHICAL AREAS WHERE THE STUDY WAS CONDUCTED l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / 直接的 . 米特 . 呃呃 / r e s t / 拉蒂斯 – df / / / / 1 0 3 3 4 1 3 1 9 2 8 4 1 3 / r e s t _ a _ 0 0 9 0 5 压力 . 来宾来访 0 7 九月 2 0 2 3 player and that he or she can decide to take some or all of the coins from the yellow envelope and transfer them to the brown one. The dictator is also informed that the coins that will be left in the yellow envelope and those transferred to the brown envelope will be the actual payoffs of the game for the passive player and for him or her, 分别. At that point, the experimenter leaves the decision room. After hav- ing decided how many coins, 如果有的话, to take from the passive player’s endowment, the dictator places the two envelopes in a box. 这样, anonymity is maintained throughout the experiment across participants, and the procedure makes it impossible for the experimenter onsite to match the players’ identities and choices. The final outcome of the game is, for both players, the amount of coins owned after the decision made by the dictator. Experimental procedure. The data collection consists of sixteen experimental sessions that took place in February and March 2017. Participants were residents of a sample of villages randomly selected from the PFR lottery pool for the province of Coffou (in the southwest of the country), THE VIRTUOUS CYCLE OF PROPERTY 417 Borgou, and Alibori (both in the northeast of Benin). The rural areas where the fieldwork for the respective studies took place are highlighted in the rectangular boxes in fig- 乌尔 1. Each session was conducted in a different village. The sixteen villages (nine treated) were randomly selected from the entire list of villages included in the lottery pool in the regions noted. No village refused to participate. The selection of participants within each village proceeded as follows. The day before the experiment, a member of the research team informed the local authority (village chief) and the village residents that the following morning, a team of re- searchers would come to the village to perform the research and recruit participants among the villagers. From the vil- lage residents who came to the meeting, the experimenters randomly selected nine male and nine female participants.9 Selected participants must have been older than 18 years old, and at maximum, one member per household was included in the experiment. In villages composed of multiple clusters of relatively isolated huts, we split equally the number of participants belonging to each cluster. A total of 254 participants took part in the study. None of the subjects had participated in an economic experi- ment before. In each session, subjects completed a brief sociodemographic survey and made decisions in the mod- ified dictator game described above, as well as in other ex- perimental tasks described in the discussion section and two additional experimental games.10 Data on participants’ risk preferences in both the domain of gains and losses were col- lected following a lottery choice task similar to Voors et al. (2012).11 To verify whether migrations between control and treated villages create selection concerns, we asked participants in our sample whether during the time frame following the re- form implementation, they had migrated from a different vil- 9Most of the sessions were completed by exactly eighteen participants; 然而, there was some variation in the number of participants, with a minimum of twelve subjects and a maximum of twenty subjects. Villagers not selected to participate in the study received a show-up fee equal to XOF 500. 10In addition to the survey and the experimental games described in this paper, during the sixteen sessions of data collection, participants took also part in a linear public goods game and a standard trust game that were part of the data collection related to a different research project. In each session, the order in which the games were played was held constant, games were played one-shot, and participants did not receive feedback regarding the game outcome until the end of the experimental session. A description of the two games that were not designed for this project are in Fabbri (2018). 11Each subject had to make six choices between participating in a lottery or gaining/losing a certain amount. In the initial three choices, participants could either play a lottery with probability 3/10 they would win 5 coins and with probability 7/10 they would win 0. The certain equivalent gain in the three lotteries was respectively 1, 1.5, 和 2 coins. In the last three choices, participants decided whether to play a lottery that implies losing 5 coins with probability 3/10 or losing 0 with probability 7/10, or incurring a certain loss of 1, 1.5, 和 2 coins. Notice that the maximum loss of 5 coins is equal to the show-up fee received and that, by design, in none of the games can participants earn negative payoffs). In order to facilitate comprehension of the choice alternatives, the experimenter used colored balls to be withdrawn from a bag for representing the probability of gains and losses and determine the outcome. A die was then thrown to determine which of the six lotteries was paid. lage and, if applicable, the reasons why they had migrated. Only two subjects were not already residents of the village where we interviewed them at the time of PFR implemen- 站, and they both reported to have migrated for reasons connected to marriage. The exclusion of these two partici- pants from the analysis leaves the results presented below qualitatively unchanged.12 Finally, in table A1 in the ap- pendix we report results of a series of t-tests (or chi-square tests for dummy variables) for the comparison of participants’ sociodemographic characteristics between the treatment and control samples. In no case did we register a statistically sig- nificant difference across the two groups. The procedures for administering the survey, the game in- structions, and the order in which the games were played were identical across sessions. Sessions took place in a pub- lic space (usually a school or a religious building), composed of a large common room and a separate room where subjects made decisions in private. Upon arrival, participants were randomly assigned an identification number and completed a brief sociodemographic questionnaire. Participants were then informed that they would earn a participation fee equal to XOF 500 and that they had the opportunity to gain addi- tional money by participating in a series of tasks. To avoid potential income effects, we also communicated that only the payoff generated in four out of seven games played during the session would be actually paid out and that the four games would be randomly determined by lottery at the end of the session. Since the majority of the participants were illiterate, exper- imental instructions for each game were administered orally in public by the experimenter.13 To minimize the risk that participants would not fully understand the instructions, each participant, before being able to enter the decision room, had to answer correctly a few control questions posed in private by the experimenter. If the participant failed to provide the correct answers, the experimenter repeated the explanation to the subject until he or she was able to answer the control questions. A session in a village lasted approximately three hours. Participants received on average $7 as final payment, 大致
the equivalent of three days’ wages for subjects in our sample.
IV.
结果
数字 2 plots the average amount of coins appropriated
by the dictators in the sample of treated participants, WHO
experienced the reform, 和, in the control sample, who did
不是. A mere inspection of the figure suggests that the average
amount of coins taken by the dictator is larger for partici-
pants in the latter sample. In figure 3, we plot the distribution
12We also asked participants in control villages whether they or their
family members owned parcels of land in neighboring treated villages.
Three subjects reported so, and we excluded them from the analysis. 这
inclusion of these three subjects in the sample does not affect the results.
13An English translation of the instructions is included in the appendix.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
418
THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
FIGURE 2.—AMOUNT OF COINS FROM OTHERS’ ENDOWMENT APPROPRIATED BY THE DICTATORS
of the amount of coins appropriated by dictators in the two
treatments. The upper panel reports the choices of partici-
pants who did not experience the land tenure reform. 这
distribution is unimodal, with a spike in correspondence on
the choice of taking five coins from the passive participants.
The lower panel shows the distribution of choices for partic-
ipants who experienced the reform. Compared to the control
sample, the distribution is skewed to the left. Taking no coins
from the other participant’s endowment is the modal choice.
This evidence suggests that, 一般, dictators in the con-
trol sample take a larger fraction of the passive players’ en-
dowments. 相似地, in figure 4, we plot the total amount of
coins taken by the dictator for each level of dictator’s choice
in the two treatments. While the majority of participants in
control villages take half of the endowment from their pairs,
villagers who experienced the reform when appropriating a
share of the passive player’s endowment mostly take less than
half of the pair’s resources.
To verify the graphical impressions obtained above, 我们
perform a Wilcoxon rank-sum test comparing the distribu-
tions of the coins appropriated by the dictators in the two
样品. The result confirms that participants in the treated
samples take significantly less of the passive players’ en-
dowment compared to those who did not experience the land
tenure reform (Wilcoxon rank-sum test, p-value < 1%). A
t-test for comparison of the mean taking rate confirms that,
on average, dictators in the treated sample take less money
from the passive participant’s endowment than those in con-
trol samples (two-sided t-test, p-value < 1%).
We compare the fraction of participants who did not ap-
propriate any coin in the two samples. Among participants in
the control sample, 5% did not take any coin from the passive
players. This percentage rises to 26% among participants in
the treated sample. A chi-square test confirms that the frac-
tion of participants taking nothing from the passive player
is significantly higher in the treated sample (chi-square test,
p-value < 1%).
We then proceed with a regression analysis. Results are
shown in table 1. We regress the amount of coins appropri-
ated by dictators on the dummy treated—that is, equal to 1 for
participants in the sample who experienced the land tenure
reform—and a set of sociodemographic controls.14 Model 1
implements an OLS regression. Standard errors are clustered
at the village level, and we use wild cluster bootstrap with 999
replications to resample with the sixteen clusters (Cameron,
Gelbach, & Miller, 2008). The coefficient of the treatment
dummy is negative and statistically significant at the 1% level,
suggesting that participants in the treated sample take signif-
icantly less than those in the control sample. In model 2, we
replicate the same specification but for using a censored tobit
regression to account for a mass point at zero coins taken
and implementing score bootstrap with 999 replications. The
result remains significant at the 1% level, confirming that
participants who experienced the reform appropriate signif-
icantly less of the passive player’s endowment than those in
the control group.15 Point estimates suggest that experienc-
ing the reform on average determines a 40% to 60% reduc-
tion of the passive players’ endowment appropriated by the
dictators.
14The controls include age, gender, village distance to paved roads, village
population, incentivized measure of risk preferences, and religion.
15In table A2 in the appendix, we replicate the regression analysis pre-
sented in table 1 by implementing a set of zero-inflated negative binomial
regression models that would account for the count nature of the data. The
results remain qualitatively unchanged.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
e
d
u
/
r
e
s
t
/
l
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
f
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
a
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
THE VIRTUOUS CYCLE OF PROPERTY
419
FIGURE 3.—DISTRIBUTION OF THE AMOUNT OF COINS APPROPRIATED BY THE DICTATORS
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
e
d
u
/
r
e
s
t
/
l
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
f
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
a
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
V.
Discussion
The evidence we have reported suggests that for the par-
ticipants in our sample, experiencing a reform transforming
collective informal land rights into a formal and legally rec-
ognized system akin to private property has a sizable effect on
the propensity to appropriate resources owned by an anony-
mous peer. In our experiment, this effect is generated indepen-
dently from other factors, such as direct peers effects, legal
norms, and enforcement institutions, which are silenced by
design.
Thus, one possible explanation for the observed behav-
ior is that experiencing formalized private property rights in-
creases respect for the property of others by directly affecting
preferences, altering the utility associated with appropriating
goods owned by others. In the discussion that follows, we
call this explanation the “endogenous respect for property
hypothesis.”
However, the behavior observed in our experiment might
be amenable to alternative explanations. For instance, partic-
ipants in treated villages might have experienced improved
material conditions, invested in education, or obtained access
to new resources—such as the ability to resort to a formal
legal system or easier access to financial means—which in
turn are related to the decrease in taking behavior. Moreover,
the reform might have triggered changes in individual values
and beliefs other than respect for property, such as an increase
in altruism, or a modification of the perception of informal
420
THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
FIGURE 4.—SUM OF THE COINS APPROPRIATED BY THE DICTATORS FOR EACH LEVEL OF DICTATOR’S TAKING
TABLE 1.—COINS APPROPRIATED BY THE DICTATOR
Model 1
−2.046
[−3.53, −.700]
0.004
Model 2
−2.518
0.001
Y
3.903
[1.818, 5.987]
127
Y
3.643
127
Model 3
−2.097
[−3.651, −.691]
0.005
−0.130
[−.567, .329]
0.52
−0.118
[−.565, .191]
0.49
0.057
[−.681, .697]
.84
Y
4.319
[2.499, 6.203]
127
Model 4
−2.525
0.001
−0.192
0.38
−0.172
0.38
0.157
0.68
Y
4.165
127
treated
C.I.
P-value
education
income10k
credit
Controls
Constant
Number of
observations
Dependent variable: coins appropriated by the dictator. Models 1 and 3: OLS regression, wild cluster
bootstrap with 999 replication. Models 2 and 4: left-censored tobit regression, score bootstrap with 999
replications. Standard errors clustered at the village level. Compared to models 1 and 2, models 3 and
4 additionally control for income (in thousands of XOF), access to credit, and education levels. Con-
trols include age, gender, religion, village distance to paved roads, village population, and estimation of
risk preferences. The two lines below the coefficient estimates report the confidence intervals (for OLS
regressions) and the p-value, respectively.
norms of redistribution, which might have affected the taking
rate. In this section, we investigate alternative explanations
for the observed behavior and contrast them with the endoge-
nous respect for property hypothesis. To do so, we analyze
additional data collected through an incentivized experiment
and a postexperimental survey.
A.
Effects of the Reform on Villagers’ Material Conditions
To explore this possibility, we compare data on participants’
income in treated and control villages. Results of a t-test
for comparison of means and of a z-test for comparison of
distributions show that there is no statistically significant dif-
ference in income between villagers in treated and control
groups (p-value > 10% in both tests). Regression analysis
reported in models 1 和 2 of table A3 in appendix A con-
firms the findings.
We also check whether obtaining formalized land rights
affected the education level of participants in our sample and
whether this fact might explain the behavior observed in the
实验. 的确, Galiani and Schargrodsky (2010) 成立
that Argentinian peri-urban squatters significantly increased
investments in education as a consequence of receiving land
titles. The majority of the rural villagers in our sample did
not receive any formal education. The fraction of partici-
pants who never went to school is statistically the same in
treated and control villages (chi-square test, p > 10%). 辛-
伊拉利, if we compare the number of school years attended
by participants belonging to treated and control groups, 这
difference is not statistically significant (t-test two-sided,
p > 10%; Wilcoxon rank-sum test, p > 10%). 这些重新-
sults are confirmed by the regression analysis reported in
table A4 in appendix A, in which we regress the number
of years of education to the treatment dummy and a set of
sociodemographic controls. 最后, in models 3 和 4 的
桌子 1, we reestimate our main model specifications pre-
sented in models 1 和 2 by adding income and education as
controls. The results remain qualitatively unaffected, 和
point estimates are very similar.
Income and education. Experiencing the reform might
have affected individual behavior through a wealth effect.
Access to credit and participation to financial activities.
One of the objectives of the PFR reform was to give land
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
THE VIRTUOUS CYCLE OF PROPERTY
421
users the possibility of collateralizing land and facilitating
the creation of a land market. Had the reform created easier
conditions for participation in financial activities and access
to credit, then villagers in the treated group might display
lower taking rates as a consequence of different exposure to
market activities. 的确, several studies discuss the possi-
bility that participation in market activities has consequences
for people’s beliefs and attitudes in the nonmarket sphere
(鲍尔斯 & Hwang, 2008).
We check whether the PFR enhanced credit supply and
exposure to financial activities for participants in our sample.
Participants were asked to report whether they were partic-
ipating or had participated in financial activities in the pre-
vious seven years and whether they had accessed the credit
market—that is, whether they had applied for a loan or mort-
量规. Engaging in these activities is relatively uncommon
in our sample. The likelihood of doing so does not differ
between the treated and control groups (chi-square test, p-
value > 10%). Regression analysis reported in table A5 in
appendix A confirms the result.
This finding is consistent with a previous assessment of the
short-term effects of Benin’s PFR on the development of a
land market (Goldstein et al., 2016) 和, 更普遍, 和
evidence suggesting a limited impact of land rights reform
programs on access to credit and financial markets (Galiani
& Schargrodsky, 2011; Lund, Odgaard, & Sjaastad, 2006).
Conflicts and conflict resolution mechanisms. An important
goal of PFR is preventing the insurgence and escalation of
conflicts over land in rural areas. Had the reform reduced the
level of conflicts experienced by participants in our sample, 它
is possible that the increase in respect for property observed
among individuals in treated villages is a consequence of the
improved relationships among community members. 对于在-
姿态, one could hypothesize that the psychological cost of
appropriating resources owned by a community member se-
lected from a sample of individuals with whom relationships
are peaceful is higher compared to a situation in which the
sample includes individuals with whom the decision maker
is currently litigating.
To verify whether the reform had an impact on the level
of conflicts, we asked participants in our experiment whether
they had experienced conflicts in the previous seven years.
The vast majority of the reported conflicts (关于 90% 的
他们) concerned land use and, 即, conflicts between
farmers and ranchers as well as boundary issues; 剩下的-
ing share of conflicts related to public takings, inheritance,
and contract enforcement. Participants in treated villages
were engaged in conflicts with the same frequency as partici-
pants in control villages (chi-squared test, p-value>10%). A
regression analysis, whose results are reported in table A6 in
appendix A, confirms the result.
We also verified whether the reform may have affected the
mechanism of conflict resolution on which villagers rely. 在
both treated and control villages, the majority of participants
who experienced conflicts continue to resort to the traditional
customary conflict resolution mechanism (89% 和 91% 在
control and treated villages, 分别). A chi-square test
cannot reject the hypothesis that the likelihood to resort to a
traditional conflict resolution mechanism is the same across
treatments.
最后, we checked whether the PFR affected the quality
of the conflict resolution mechanism. 例如, Deininger
and Feder (2009) argue that the introduction of a new formal
judicial system—at least in the short term—might not replace
the traditional customary dispute resolution mechanism, 但
rather may create a parallel judicial channel that makes it
possible for litigants to engage in forum shopping, thus com-
plicating and delaying the resolution of conflicts. 这样做,
we asked the fifty participants who reported having experi-
enced a conflict whether the conflicts they experienced had
been successfully solved. We find no statistically significant
difference in this measure between respondents in treated and
control villages (chi-square test, p-value>10%).
乙.
Effects of the Reform on Altruism, Distributional Norms,
and Pro-Market Beliefs
Altruism. An alternative explanation to the endogenous
respect for property hypothesis is that participants who expe-
rienced the property rights reform were subject to an increase
in pure altruism. Should that be the case, more altruistic dic-
tators would allocate a larger fraction of the endowment to
the passive player, independent of whether they are donating
part of their endowment (as in the standard dictator game) 或者
taking resources from the passive player (as in our modified
dictator game).
To verify whether the observed reduction in taking can be
explained through a change in altruistic preferences, we asked
the same subjects who acted as dictators in our taking dic-
tator game to participate in a standard dictator game framed
as a donation choice. In this game, participants initially re-
ceived from the experimenter 10 coins worth XOF 100 each.
The participants were then informed that they could choose
to donate some or all of the coins received to an orphanage.
Following the same procedure that was adopted in the modi-
fied dictator game, the participants’ donation decisions were
blind to the experimenter on site.
数字 5 plots the average amount of coins donated in
treated and control villages. Participants in villages who ex-
perienced the reform on average donate less than those in con-
trol villages (2.9 相对 3.25, 分别), albeit the mean
donation and the distribution of donation choices are not sta-
tistically different between treated and control participants
(t-test two-sided p > 10%; Mann-Whitney test two-sided,
p > 10%). Table A7 in the appendix, in which we replicate
the analysis presented in table 1 but for using as a dependent
variable the amount of coins donated, confirms that there are
no statistically significant differences in donation rate be-
tween treatments. 所以, in our sample, experiencing the
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
422
THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
FIGURE 5.—COINS DONATED BY PARTICIPANTS IN A DICTATOR GAME FRAMED AS A DONATION DECISION
land tenure reform did not produce a significant increase in
villagers’ altruism that could explain the observed increase
in respecting others’ property.
Beliefs regarding others’ altruism and profit redistribution.
A possible explanation for the lower taking rate recorded
among treated participants is that the reform changed their
beliefs regarding how other villagers would behave in the
same situation, and these modified expectations in turn deter-
mined the observed change in behavior. 例如, 莱文
(1998) proposes a model of behavior in which the level of
prosociality displayed by an agent depends on her beliefs re-
garding what others in her reference group will do in the same
situation.
A different behavioral mechanism that would lead to sim-
ilar results is that if agents derive utility from conforming to
the behavioral standard of the reference group, a participant
might reduce her taking rate because of the expectation that
after the PFR implementation, others will also do so (Hung &
Plott, 2001; Manski, 2000). 所以, had the reform modi-
fied expectations regarding how other villagers would behave
in the role of dictator, the observed reduction in taking for
treated subjects might be explained in terms of a change in
beliefs rather than preferences.
To verify whether, in treated villages, the reform affected a
participant’s expectations regarding his or her peers’ willing-
ness to respect property rights, we asked passive players how
many coins they expected the dictator to appropriate from
their endowment. 数字 6 plots the average beliefs regard-
ing dictators’ taking rate reported by passive players across
treatments. 平均而言, passive players underestimated the
amount of coins effectively taken by the dictators. We do
not find evidence that there is an expectation of enhanced re-
spect for property in treated villages. If anything, in treated
villages, passive players expect more taking from the dicta-
tors compared to those in control villages (3.27 相对 2.69,
分别), albeit the difference is only marginally statisti-
cally significant (t-test two-sided, p-value<10%; Wilcoxon
rank-sum test two-sided, p-value<10%).
We also checked whether the reform affected the social
norms for profit redistribution. To test this possibility, using
an incentivized coordination games similar to Krupka & We-
ber (2013), we elicited a set of social norms concerning the
distributions of profits from an investment. Subjects were in-
centivized to correctly guess how much the majority of the
village would consider it appropriate to share profits pro-
portionally to initial investments made by each party instead
of performing an egalitarian split.16 A Kruskal-Wallis test
cannot reject the hypothesis that participants in treated and
control villages share the same perception of shared social
norms regarding egalitarian versus meritocratic division of
earned income (p > 10%).
Beliefs regarding individualism, importance of money, 和
In a postexperimental survey, we col-
self-determination.
lected nonincentivized measures concerning a set of beliefs
that are associated with favoring the development of a free-
market economy (Di Tella, Galiani, & Schargrodsky, 2007).
If affected by the reform, these beliefs might have affected
16Participants were described a situation in which two parties make a
joint investment contributing unequal initial amounts of resources. 这
subjects could rate the decision to split the profits obtained (A) equally and
(乙) proportionally to the initial contribution to the investment. Specifically,
participants must choose from four options: “Very socially inappropriate,”
“Somewhat socially inappropriate,” “Somewhat socially appropriate,“ 和
“Very socially appropriate.” The complete instructions to the coordination
game are reported in appendix B.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
THE VIRTUOUS CYCLE OF PROPERTY
423
FIGURE 6.—AMOUNT OF COINS THAT PASSIVE PLAYERS EXPECT THE DICTATORS WILL TAKE FROM THEIR ENDOWMENTS
participants’ respect for others’ property. 这样做, we asked a
set of questions taken from the World Values Survey.17 First,
we focused on measures of individualism versus collectivism
by asking whether participants believe that success requires
a large group or can be achieved alone. The vast majority
of participants in our sample (87%) consider a large group
a necessary condition to achieve success. A chi-square test
shows that there is no statistically significant difference in be-
liefs regarding individualism and collectivism in our sample
(p-value > 10%).
第二, we asked participants their beliefs regarding the
importance of work, as opposed to luck, to achieve success.
总共, 36% of our respondents consider work important
to achieve success. These subjects are evenly distributed be-
tween the treated (37%) and the control (35%) 团体. A
chi-square test fails to reject the hypothesis that the differ-
ence in response rate across the two groups is statistically
significant.
第三, we asked participants a question regarding the im-
portance of money for happiness. In our sample, 9% of the re-
spondents state that money is not important, 52% that money
is important to some extent, 和 40% that money is very im-
重要的. A Kruskal-Wallis test fails to reject the hypothesis
that the response rates differ across treatments.
Unobserved local characteristics and learning from neigh-
boring villages. 最后, we compare the behavior of treated
and control villages separating those located in the north of
国家 (where the distance between villages is larger)
and the south (where villages are comparatively closer to
17The complete text of questions that were asked is reported in
appendix B.
each other’s), 分别. Under the assumption that villages
closer to each other share more homogeneous characteristics
and cultural traits, if neighboring villages behave very dif-
ferently, that would rule out possible channels explaining the
observed results such as unobserved cultural characteristics
at a local level. Another possibility is that simply observing
(rather than experiencing directly) the formalization of prop-
erty rights in neighboring villages is sufficient to determine
a shift in subjects’ willingness to respect others’ property.
Assuming that villages geographically located closer to each
other have more opportunities to interact and observe neigh-
bors, if this hypothesis holds, we should expect participants
resident in the southern region, where villages are located
closer to each other compared to those in the north, to behave
more similarly across treatment groups.18
In figures 7 和 8, we plot the distribution and mean taking
rate of the dictators in the north and in the south, 分别.
Both the distribution and the average taking rate in the two
subgroups mimic those we registered in the aggregate. 在
特别的, the increase in respect for others’ property rights
after having experienced the reform seems to be the largest
for villagers in the southern region.
The finding is confirmed by regression analysis reported in
tables A8 and A9 in the appendix, in which we replicate the
regression analysis proposed in table 1, including only the
subsample of more dispersed villages in the northern region
and only the subsample of villages in the more densely popu-
lated southern region, 分别. These results suggest that
in both regions, experiencing the reform significantly reduces
18An important caveat is that the analysis comprises only data from sixteen
villages and the statistical power limited. 所以, while the findings
reported in this section provide suggestive evidence regarding these two
channels, readers should take into account these limitations.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
424
THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
FIGURE 7.—DISTRIBUTION OF DICTATOR’S TAKING RATE BY REGION
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
the amount of coins taken by dictators, and do not support
the hypothesis that the effect is driven by background unob-
servables or by a learning-from-neighbors process.
六、.
结论
This paper investigates how a major change in the struc-
ture of property rights over land affects respect for property.
We study a reform implemented in Benin from 2009 到 2011
by the World Bank. The reform resulted in the registration
and formalization of rights over land, turning the existing
collective customary rights over land into individual rights
akin to private property. Our identification strategy relies on
the unique process of implementation of this reform, 第一个
case of large-scale land tenure reform implemented as a ran-
domized control trial. Seven years after the reform imple-
心理状态, we conducted a set of laboratory experiments im-
plementing a modified dictator game in which participants
can appropriate others’ endowments, while enforcement in-
stitutions are silenced.
We show that the reform significantly and substantially
lowered the willingness of Beninese villagers to appropri-
ate the endowments of others in a modified dictator game.
We attribute this result to a change in preferences for re-
spect for property and exclude competing explanations based
on changes in material conditions, 信仰, or other prefer-
ences using additional experimental measures and a post-
experimental survey.
These findings demonstrate that the structure and design of
property rights institutions may have important consequences
for social preferences. In this respect, this paper is broadly re-
lated to the literature investigating the relationship between
acquiring property rights and economic prosperity. 学校-
ars have shown that tenure security is a key determinant for
increasing residential investments, labor supply, 教育,
and social capital accumulation (Field, 2005, 2007; Galiani
THE VIRTUOUS CYCLE OF PROPERTY
425
FIGURE 8.—AVERAGE DICTATOR’S TAKING RATE BY REGION
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
& Schargrodsky, 2010; DiPasquale & Glaeser, 1999). 这
findings of Di Tella, Galiani, and Schargrodsky (2007) 苏格-
gest that one avenue through which well-defined property
rights could determine these improvements is by reinforcing
pro-market beliefs. More radically, McCloskey (2010) aims
at dispelling the idea that property rights matter at all. 她
argues that it is the “liberty” and in particular the “dignity”—
那是, respect for work, 创业精神, and innovation—
afforded to those involved in productive activities that have
fostered growth over the past centuries. Our results shed light
on a possible additional channel. Formalizing property rights
activates a virtuous cycle of first-party enforcement in the
form of an internalized norm of behavior supporting respect
for property—possibly, a form of dignity.
Tentatively, our results suggest that formalizing property
rights may have a positive feedback effect on the costs of
enforcing such rights, since part of it possibly comes in
the form of inexpensive (from the perspective of public
当局) first-party enforcement, reducing the scope for
formal enforcement institutions. Reflecting on two waves of
law and development reforms—of which the formalization
of property rights is an important component—Berkowitz,
Pistor, and Richard (2003) argue that the successful trans-
plantation of Western legal institution requires a “receptive”
environment and that recent history provides countless ex-
amples of failure to take into account local institutional and
cultural conditions. Here we show that there could be an ad-
ditional inverse relationship between institutional transplants
426
THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
and local conditions: the process of transplantation could con-
tribute to alter those conditions.
最后, a possible channel explaining the results observed
could be that the reform affected the evolution of fairness
规范 (Almås et al., 2010).19 In our experiment, 大多数
of participants in the control sample choose a taking rate that
produces an egalitarian distribution of the endowments, 尽管
participants who experienced better-defined property rights
predominantly choose to not take anything from the pair’s
财产, thus abandoning the fifty-fifty rule of resources al-
地点. While our study was not designed to investigate the
impact of the reform on distributional preferences and so we
can only provide suggestive evidence of these effects, 我们
believe that studying how property rights institutions shape
people’s acceptance of inequality can be an interesting topic
for future research.
19We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this possible explana-
的.
参考
Acemoglu, Daron, 西蒙·约翰逊, 和詹姆斯A.. 罗宾逊, “Institutions
as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth” (PP. 385–472), 在
Philippe Aghion and Steven Durlauf, 编辑。, Handbook of Economic
生长 (阿姆斯特丹: 爱思唯尔, 2005).
Alesina, 阿尔贝托, and Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln, “Good-Bye Lenin (或者
不是?): The Effect of Communism on People’s Preferences,” Amer-
ican Economic Review 97 (2007), 1507–1528.
Alesina, 阿尔贝托, and Paola Giuliano, “Culture and Institutions,“ 杂志
of Economic Literature 53 (2015), 898–944.
Almås, Ingvild, Alexander W. Cappelen, Erik Ø. Sørensen, and Bertil Tun-
Godden, “Fairness and the Development of Inequality Acceptance,”
科学 328 (2010), 1176–1178.
Arruñada, Benito, Giorgio Zanarone, and Nuno Garoupam, “Property
Rights in Sequential Exchange,” Journal of Law, 经济学, 和
组织机构 35 (2018), 127–153.
Ayres, Ian, and Steven D. 莱维特, “Measuring Positive Externalities from
Unobservable Victim Precaution: An Empirical Analysis of Lojack,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 113 (1998), 43–77.
Ban, Radu, 迈克尔·J. Gilligan, and Matthias Riege, “Self-Help Groups,
Savings and Social Capital: Evidence from a Field Experiment in
Cambodia” (华盛顿, 直流: World Bank, 2015).
Bardsley, 尼古拉斯, “Dictator Game Giving: Altruism or Artefact?” Exper-
imental Economics 11 (2008), 122–133.
Barr, Abigail, Justine Burns, Luis Miller, and Ingrid Shaw, “Economic
Status and Acknowledgement of Earned Entitlement,》杂志
Economic Behavior and Organization 118 (2015), 55–68.
Barr, Abigail, and Mattea Stein, “Status and Egalitarianism in Traditional
Communities: An Analysis of Funeral Attendance in Six Zimbab-
wean Villages” (牛津: Centre for the Study of African Economies,
牛津大学, 2008).
Becker, Sascha O., Katrin Boeckh, Christa Hainz, and Ludger Woessmann,
“The Empire Is Dead, Long Live the Empire! Long-Run Persistence
of Trust and Corruption in the Bureaucracy,” Economic Journal 126
(2016), 40–74.
Berkowitz, Daniel, Katharina Pistor, and Jean-François Richard, “这
Transplant Effect,” American Journal of Comparative Law 51
(2003), 163–204.
Bernard, Tanguy, Alain De Janvry, and Elisabeth Sadoulet, “什么时候
Does Community Conservatism Constrain Village Organizations?”
Economic Development and Cultural Change 58 (2010), 609–
641.
Bigoni, Maria, Stefania Bortolotti, Marco Casari, Diego Gambetta, 和
Francesca Pancotto, “Amoral Familism, Social Capital, or Trust?
The Behavioural Foundations of the Italian North–South Divide,”
Economic Journal 126 (2016), 1318–1341.
Bolle, Friedel, Jonathan H. 瓦. Tan, and Daniel John Zizzo, “Vendettas,”
American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 6 (2014), 93–130.
Bó, Pedro Dal, Andrew Foster, and Louis Putterman, “Institutions and Be-
行为: Experimental Evidence on the Effects of Democracy,” Amer-
ican Economic Review 100 (2010), 2205–2229.
Botticini, Maristella, and Zvi Eckstein, “From Farmers to Merchants, 骗局-
versions and Diaspora: Human Capital and Jewish History,“ 杂志
of the European Economic Association 5 (2007), 885–926.
鲍尔斯, 塞缪尔, and Sung-Ha Hwang, “Social Preferences and Public Eco-
经济学: Mechanism Design When Social Preferences Depend on
Incentives,” 公共经济学杂志 92 (2008), 1811–1820.
Cameron, A. Colin, Jonah B. Gelbach, and Douglas L. 磨坊主, “Bootstrap-
Based Improvements for Inference with Clustered Errors,” this RE-
VIEW 90 (2008), 414–427.
Cappelen, Alexander W., Ulrik H. Nielsen, Erik Ø. Sørensen, Bertil Tun-
godden, and Jean-Robert Tyran, “Give and Take in Dictator Games,”
Economics Letters 118 (2013), 280–283.
Charness, Gary, and Matthew Rabin, “Understanding Social Preferences
with Simple Tests,》 经济学季刊 117 (2002),
817–869.
Chauveau, Jean-Pierre, Pierre-Marie Bosc, and Michel Pescay, “Le plan
foncier rural en Côte d’Ivoire,” in Philippe Lavigne Delville,
编辑。, Quelles politiques foncières en Afrique rurale (Coopération
française, 1996).
Croson, 雷切尔, and Simon Gächter, “The Science of Experimental Eco-
经济学,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 73
(2010), 122–131.
Deininger, Klaus, and Raffaella Castagnini, “Incidence and Impact of Land
Conflict in Uganda,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organiza-
的 60 (2006), 321–345.
Deininger, Klaus, and Gershon Feder, “Land Registration, Governance, 和
发展: Evidence and Implications for Policy,” World Bank
Research Observer 24 (2009), 233–266.
Delville, 磷. L。, “Harmonising Formal Law and Customary Land Rights in
French-Speaking West Africa” (PP. 97–122), in Camilla Toulmin
and Julian Quan, 编辑。, Evolving Land Rights, Policy and Tenure in
West Africa (纽约: 牛津大学出版社, 2006).
——— “Registering and Administering Customary Land Rights: PFRs in
West Africa,” in World Bank Conference on Land Policies and Legal
Empowerment of the Poor (华盛顿, 直流: World Bank, 2006).
DiPasquale, Denise, and Edward L. Glaeser, “Incentives and Social Capital:
Are Homeowners Better Citizens?” Journal of Urban Economics 45
(1999), 354–384.
Di Tella, Rafael, Sebastian Galiani, and Ernesto Schargrodsky, “The For-
mation of Beliefs: Evidence from the Allocation of Land Titles
to Squatters,》 经济学季刊 122 (2007), 209–
241.
Dreber, 安娜, Tore Ellingsen, Magnus Johannesson, and David G. Rand,
“Do People Care about Social Context? Framing Effects in Dictator
Games,” Experimental Economics 16 (2013), 349–371.
Eswaran, 穆克什, and Hugh M. Neary, “An Economic Theory of the Evo-
lutionary Emergence of Property Rights,” American Economic Jour-
纳尔: Microeconomics 6 (2014), 203–226.
Fabbri, Marco, “How Institutions Shape Culture: Evidence from a Land
Rights Reform Implemented as Randomized Control-Trial,” tech-
nical paper (2018), SSRN 3054535, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.
3054535.
Fabbri, Marco, and Emanuela Carbonara, “Social Influence on Third-Party
惩罚: An Experiment,” Journal of Economic Psychology 62
(2017), 204–230.
Fabbri, Marco, Matteo Rizzolli, and Antonello Maruotti, “Possession Is
Nine-Tenths of the Law: Bourgeois Behavior, Property and In-
equality in an Hawk–Dove Experiment,” University of Amsterdam
(2018).
Faillo, Marco, Matteo Rizzolli, and Stephan Tontrup, “Thou Shalt Not Steal:
Taking Aversion with Legal Property Claims,” Journal of Economic
心理学 71 (2019), 88–101.
Field, Erica, “Property Rights and Investment in Urban Slums,》杂志
the European Economic Association 3 (2005), 279–290.
——— “Entitled to Work: Urban Property Rights and Labor Supply in
秘鲁,》 经济学季刊 122 (2007), 1561–1602.
Fisman, 雷蒙德, Pamela Jakiela, Shachar Kariv, and Daniel Markovits,
“The Distributional Preferences of an Elite,“ 科学 349 (2015),
aab0096.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
THE VIRTUOUS CYCLE OF PROPERTY
427
Galiani, Sebastian, and Ernesto Schargrodsky, “Property Rights for the
Poor: Effects of Land Titling,” 公共经济学杂志 94
(2010), 700–729.
——— “Land Property Rights and Resource Allocation,” Journal of Law
and Economics 54 (2011), S329–S345.
Gintis, 赫伯特, “The Evolution of Private Property,” Journal of Economic
Behavior and Organization 64 (2007), 1–16.
Glaeser, Edward L., Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de Silanes, and An-
drei Shleifer, “Do Institutions Cause Growth?” Journal of Economic
生长 9 (2004), 271–303.
Gneezy, Uri, Andreas Leibbrandt, 和约翰·A. List, “Ode to the Sea: 工作-
place Organizations and Norms of Cooperation,” Economic Journal
595 (2016), 1856–1883.
戈德斯坦, Markus P., Kenneth Houngbedji, Florence Kondylis, Michael B.
O’Sullivan, and Harris Selod, “Formalizing Rural Land Rights in
West Africa: Early Evidence from a Randomized Impact Evaluation
in Benin” (华盛顿, 直流: World Bank, 2016).
Grechenig, Kristoffel, Andreas Nicklisch, and Christian Thöni, “Punish-
ment Despite Reasonable Doubt: A Public Goods Experiment with
Sanctions under Uncertainty,” 实证法律研究杂志 7
(2010), 847–867.
Gruber, 乔纳森, and Daniel M. Hungerman, “The Church versus the Mall:
What Happens When Religion Faces Increased Secular Competi-
的?》 经济学季刊 123 (2018), 831–862.
Hare, Darragh, Hudson Kern Reeve, and Bernd Blossey, “Evolutionary
Routes to Stable Ownership,” Journal of Evolutionary Biology 29
(2016), 1178–1188.
Heaton, 保罗, Priscillia Hunt, John MacDonald, and Jessica Saunders, “这
Short- and Long-Run Effects of Private Law Enforcement: 证据
from University Police,” Journal of Law and Economics 59 (2016),
889–912.
Henrich, 约瑟夫, 罗伯特·博伊德, Samuel Bowles, Colin Camerer, Ernst Fehr,
赫伯特·德防御, and Richard McElreath, “In Search of Homo Eco-
nomicus: Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies,”
American Economic Review 91 (2001), 73–78.
Henrich, 约瑟夫, Steven J. Heine, and Ara Norenzayan, “The Weirdest
People in the World?” Behavioral and Brain Science 33 (2010),
61–135.
亨利, John F., “John Locke, Property Rights, and Economic Theory,”
Journal of Economic Issues 33 (1999), 609–624.
Herrmann, Benedikt, Christian Thöni, and Simon Gächter, “Antisocial Pun-
ishment across Societies,“ 科学 319 (2008), 1362–1367.
霍奇森, Geoffrey M., “Much of the ‘Economics of Property Rights’ De-
values Property and Legal Rights,” Journal of Institutional Eco-
经济学 11 (2015), 683–709.
Hung, Angela A., and Charles R. Plott, “Information Cascades: Replica-
tion and an Extension to Majority Rule and Conformity-Rewarding
机构,” 美国经济评论 91 (2001), 1508–1520.
Jakiela, Pamela, “Social Preferences and Fairness Norms as Informal Insti-
tutions: Experimental Evidence,” 美国经济评论 101
(2011), 509–513.
——— “Using Economic Experiments to Measure Informal Institutions,”
在S. Galliani, 和我. Sened, 编辑。, 机构, Property Rights, 和
经济增长: The Legacy of Douglass North (剑桥:
剑桥大学出版社, 2014).
——— “How Fair Shares Compare: Experimental Evidence from Two Cul-
特雷斯,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 118 (2015),
40–54.
Jakiela, Pamela, Edward Miguel, and Vera L. Te Velde, “You’ve Earned
它: Estimating the Impact of Human Capital on Social Preferences,”
Experimental Economics 18 (2015), 385–407.
约翰逊, Dominic D. P。, and Monica Duffy Toft, “Bringing ‘Geo’ Back
into Politics: 进化, Territoriality and the Contest over Ukraine,”
Cliodynamics: Journal of Quantitative History and Cultural Evolu-
的 5:1 (2014).
Khadjavi, Menusch, “On the Interaction of Deterrence and Emotions,” Jour-
nal of Law, 经济学, and Organization 31 (2015), 287–319.
Kokko, Hanna, “Dyadic Contests: Modelling Flights between Two Individ-
uals” (PP. 5–32), in Ian C. 瓦. Hardy and Mark Briffa, 编辑。, Animal
Contests (剑桥: 剑桥大学出版社, 2013).
Korenok, Oleg, Edward L. Millner, and Laura Razzolini, “Taking Aver-
锡安,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 150 (2018),
397–403.
Krupka, Erin L., and Roberto A. 韦伯, “Identifying Social Norms Us-
ing Coordination Games: Why Does Dictator Game Sharing Vary?”
Journal of the European Economic Association 11:3 (2013), 495–
524.
莱文, D. K., “Modeling Altruism and Spitefulness in Experiments,“ 关于-
view of Economic Dynamics 1 (1998), 593–622.
List, John A., “On the Interpretation of Giving in Dictator Games,“ 杂志
of Political Economy 115 (2007), 482–493.
洛克, 约翰. Second Treatise of Government: An Essay Concerning the
True Original, Extent and End of Civil Government (霍博肯, 新泽西州:
威利, 2014).
Loewenstein, 乔治, “Experimental Economics from the Vantage-Point
of Behavioural Economics,” Economic Journal 109 (1999), 25–34.
Lucas, Adrienne M., Patrick J. McEwan, Moses Ngware, and Moses
Oketch, “Improving Early-Grade Literacy In East Africa: Experi-
mental Evidence from Kenya and Uganda,” Journal of Policy Anal-
ysis and Management 33 (2014), 950–976.
Lund, Christian, Rie Odgaard, and Espen Sjaastad, Land Rights and Land
Conflicts in Africa: A Review of Issues and Experiences (Copen-
hagen: DIIS, 2006).
Manski, Charles F., “Economic Analysis of Social Interactions,“ 杂志
of Economic Perspectives 14 (2000), 115–136.
McCloskey, Deirdre N., Bourgeois Dignity: Why Economics Can’t Explain
the Modern World (芝加哥: 芝加哥大学出版社, 2010).
Merrill, Thomas W., and Henry E. 史密斯, “What Happened to Property in
Law and Economics,” Yale Law Journal 111 (2001), 357.
Mokyr, Joel, “Intellectual Property Rights, the Industrial Revolution, 和
the Beginnings of Modern Economic growth,” American Economic
审查 99 (2009), 349–355.
Nikiforakis, N。, “Punishment and Counter-Punishment in Public Good
Games: Can We Really Govern Ourselves?” Journal of Public Eco-
经济学 92 (2008), 91–112.
北, Douglass C., “Institutions,” 经济展望杂志 5
(1991), 97–112.
Oxoby, Robert J., and John Spraggon, “Mine and Yours: Property Rights in
Dictator Games,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization
65 (2008), 703–713.
Paluck, Elizabeth Levy, and Donald P. 绿色的, “Deference, Dissent, 和
Dispute Resolution: An Experimental Intervention Using Mass Me-
dia to Change Norms and Behavior in Rwanda,” American Political
Science Review 103 (2009), 622–644.
Pape, 右. A。, “The Strategic Logic of Suicide Terrorism,” American Political
Science Review 97 (2003), 343–361.
Platteau, Jean-Philippe, 机构, Social Norms and Economic Develop-
蒙特 (阿姆斯特丹: Harwood, 2000).
Rodriguez-Sickert, Carlos, Ricardo Andrés Guzmán, and Juan Camilo Cár-
denas, “Institutions Influence Preferences: Evidence from a Com-
mon Pool Resource Experiment,” Journal of Economic Behavior
and Organization 67 (1), 215–227.
Sääksvuori, Lauri, Johannes Hewig, Holger Hecht, and Wolfgang H. 右.
Miltner, “A Neural Signature of Private Property Rights,“ 杂志
of Neuroscience, 心理学, and Economics 9(1), 38.
Schram, Arthur, “Artificiality: The Tension between Internal and External
Validity in Economic Experiments,” Journal of Economic Method-
ology 12 (2005), 225–237.
史密斯, Vernon L., “Economics in the Laboratory,” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 8 (1994), 113–131.
Sutter, 马蒂亚斯, Stefan Haigner, and Martin G. Kocher, “Choosing the %
or the Stick? Endogenous Institutional Choice in Social Dilemma
Situations,” Review of Economic Studies 77 (4), 1540–1566.
Voors, Maarten J., Eleonora E. 中号. Nillesen, Philip Verwimp, Erwin H.
Bulte, Robert Lensink, and Daan P. Van Soest, “Violent Conflict
and Behavior: A Field Experiment in Burundi,” American Economic
审查 102 (2012), 941–964.
Zeki, S。, Goodenough, 氧. R。, and Jeffrey Evans Stake, “The Property ‘In-
stinct,’” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London.
Series B: Biological Sciences 359 (1451), 1763–1774.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
e
d
你
/
r
e
s
t
/
我
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
F
/
/
/
/
1
0
3
3
4
1
3
1
9
2
8
4
1
3
/
r
e
s
t
_
A
_
0
0
9
0
5
p
d
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3