The Effects of Formalization on Small and
Medium-Sized Enterprise Tax Payments:
Panel Evidence from Viet Nam
Amadou Boly∗
Do firms pay more taxes after formalization? The answer to this question is
nontrivial. Tax noncompliance can be a persistent behavior among formerly
informal firms. Analyzing the relationship between formalization and tax
payments can also be challenging if nonswitching and switching firms have
different characteristics. I use a panel dataset built from five small and
medium-sized enterprise surveys conducted in Viet Nam from 2005 到 2013.
By comparing nonswitching informal firms to switchers, I show that switchers
are more likely to pay taxes and to pay a higher amount, thereby confirming
heterogeneity. By comparing switchers before and after formalization, I find
that formalization increases tax payment likelihood by 20% and the tax amount
paid by 93%. A control function approach indicates that my results are
robust to potential endogeneity of formalization. 所以, this paper provides
supportive evidence for a key public policy rationale to promote formalization:
increased tax revenues.
关键词: formalization, 税收, Viet Nam
JEL codes: D22, O12, O17
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
我. 介绍
Existing research has mainly focused on the private costs and benefits
of formalization for informal firms, with available evidence suggesting that
formalization can have a positive effect on firm performance (McKenzie and Sakho
2010; Fajnzylber, Maloney, and Montes-Rojas 2011; Rand and Torm 2012; Bruhn
and McKenzie 2014; 博利 2018).1 In contrast to most previous studies, 这篇论文
∗Amadou Boly: African Development Bank, Abidjan, Côte d’Ivoire. 电子邮件: a.boly@afdb.org. This article is
published here with due acknowledgement of UNU-WIDER, Helsinki, which commissioned the original research
under the project Structural Transformation and Inclusive Growth in Viet Nam. I am grateful to the Development
Economics Research Group at the University of Copenhagen for granting access to the Viet Nam data, 尤其
Finn Tarp, and to Christina Kinghan for constructing the panel dataset. I would also like to thank Robert Gillanders,
Anthony Mveyange, and Robert D. Osei, the managing editor and the anonymous referees for helpful comments and
suggestions. The views expressed here are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the African
Development Bank Group. ADB recognizes “Vietnam” as Viet Nam. The usual ADB disclaimer applies.
1Formalization, which is viewed as a deliberate private decision by the firm taken after cost–benefit analysis,
occurs when its perceived net benefits are positive (Maloney 2004; De Mel, 麦肯齐, and Woodruff 2013).
Asian Development Review, 卷. 37, 不. 1, PP. 140–158
https://doi.org/10.1162/adev_a_00144
© 2020 Asian Development Bank and
Asian Development Bank Institute.
在知识共享下发布
归因 3.0 国际的 (抄送 3.0) 执照.
The Effects of Formalization on SME Tax Payments in Viet Nam 141
asks whether a government can also benefit from formalization through additional
tax payments resulting from firms opting out of the informal sector.
Tax payments are costs to firms, and these costs will increase as a direct
consequence of formalization only if there is (partial or full) compliance with
formal tax regulations. 然而, noncompliance with formal tax or labor regulations can
persist among formerly informal firms; noncompliance is a common phenomenon
even among formal firms, including in member countries of the Organisation
for Economic Co-operation and Development (经合组织 2008).2 In consequence,
the claim that formalization increases government revenues is ultimately an
empirical question, the answer to which can strengthen (或不) a key public policy
rationale for promoting the formalization of small and medium-sized enterprises
(中小企业).3
Analyzing the effects of formalization on informal firms is challenging due to
potential firm heterogeneity. Heterogeneity can come from the fact that firms opting
out of the informal sector have different characteristics (例如, owner capabilities and
firm preferences) compared with those that remain informal. 而且, unobserved
characteristics that affect firm outcomes may lead to formalization; 如果, 例如,
more successful firms become more visible, leading to a higher likelihood to register
formally (McKenzie and Sakho 2010; Fajnzylber, Maloney, and Montes-Rojas
2011).
To study the relationship between formalization and tax payments, I applied
regression analysis to a panel dataset compiled using five SME surveys from Viet
Nam. I restricted the dataset to informal firms that remained informal throughout
the survey periods and to informal firms that became formal at a given point
in time (referred to as switching firms or formalized firms). Informality is a
multidimensional concept that is difficult to define. 然而, for my purpose,
formal firms are defined as those that registered to pay tax (obtained a tax code),
which is a commonly used indicator of formality in the literature (McKenzie and
Sakho 2010, Rand and Torm 2012).4
McKenzie and Sakho (2010) hypothesize that a profit-maximizing firm becomes formal if and only if the expected
present discounted value of the net benefits from doing so outweighs the upfront costs:
时间(西德:2)
δt E(πF,t − πI,t ) + θlaw-abiding > CMoney + CTime + CInformation
t=1
where πF,t denotes the firm’s profits if it is formally registered at time t, and πI,t denotes the firm’s profits if it is not
formally registered at time t. θlaw-abiding denotes the utility benefit to firm owners from obeying the law and feeling
they are contributing to national welfare through paying taxes. CMoney, CTime, and CInformation denote the monetary, 时间,
and information costs of registering, 分别.
2See also Basu, Chau, and Kanbur (2010) and Tedds (2010).
3See Bruhn and McKenzie (2014), who consider that the claim that formalization is socially optimal because
it increases government revenues and reinforces a culture of respecting the rule of the law, requires more research.
4An operational definition based on business registration would be consistent with the International Labour
Organization’s (2003) definition of informal sector enterprises, which are basically “unregistered and/or small-scale
private unincorporated enterprises that produce goods or services for sale or barter.” Other criteria of informal
employment include employment contract registration, provision of social security protection, and size of the
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
142 Asian Development Review
然而, the absence of registration does not mean that the informal sector
is not taxed, as a nonnegligible fraction of informal firms pay some sort of taxes
in Viet Nam, albeit mostly local taxes (Cling, Razafindrakoto, and Roubaud 2011,
p. 33).5 It is therefore important to ascertain that formalization leads to additional
tax payments by switching firms beyond and above what was already paid.
Using the formal status variable (status equals 0 if a firm is informal and 1
if formal), I constructed a variable called switcher, which equals 1 for all years in
which a switching firm has been observed in my sample, including the years before
formalization, 和 0 if the firm remained informal throughout the survey periods.
The switcher variable, as firm-type fixed effects, allows for capturing heterogeneity
between firms remaining informal and firms that switched out of the informal
sector at some point. 因此, when included in my regression, the variable
地位, which takes a value of 1 only for switching firms after they have formalized,
captures the net effect of formalization on switching firms.
formalization,
By comparing nonswitching informal firms to switchers,
I confirm
heterogeneity between switching firms and nonswitching firms regarding tax
付款: switchers paid a significantly higher amount of taxes than nonswitchers.
然后, by comparing switchers before and after
I find that
formalization increases the likelihood of tax payment (经过 20%) and the amount
of taxes (经过 93%) relative to preformalization levels. This significant increase
in tax payments persists both in the short and long term. Using a control
function approach, I show that my results are robust to potential endogeneity of
formalization. I also find that the increase in tax payments is mainly driven by
a significant increase in the payment of taxes such as license fees or import and
export taxes, but not in the payment of revenue taxes that are arguably more difficult
to collect. Firm size, previous performance, and compliance inspection all have a
positive relationship with both the amount and likelihood of tax payments.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section II briefly
literature on the effects of
presents an overview of the existing empirical
formalization. I describe my dataset in section III and explain the empirical
approach in section IV. Section V presents the main results and section VI
concludes.
二. Literature Review
The literature on the relationship between formalization and firm
performance has mainly focused on the private benefits for a firm. Comparing
employer (Henley, Arabsheibani, and Carneiro 2009). 然而, compared to having a tax code, these other definitions
may not be best fits, given that I am seeking whether formalization leads to additional tax payments.
5See also Olken and Singhal (2011) for a discussion of informal taxation in 10 developing economies,
including Viet Nam.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
The Effects of Formalization on SME Tax Payments in Viet Nam 143
firms that were created immediately before and after a business tax reduction and
simplification scheme in Brazil, Fajnzylber, Maloney, and Montes-Rojas (2011)
find that this scheme led to increased levels of registration and to higher revenues,
profits, and employment among registered firms. 同样地, 夏尔马 (2014) suggests
that registration leads to significant gains in both sales and value added per
employee in India. In Bolivia, McKenzie and Sakho (2010) analyze the effects
of formalization on firm profits, using the physical distance between a firm and
the tax office as an instrument. The assumption is that being closer to a tax office
increases the probability of registration. Their findings suggest that the effect of
tax registration is positive but heterogeneous. Related to the research question in
the current paper, McKenzie and Sakho (2010) also show that registered firms are
more likely to pay taxes, but not significantly more likely to be paying a larger share
of their profits as taxes.
In contrast to most previous cross-section studies, Rand and Torm (2012)
use the same panel data as in this study, but only for 2007 和 2009. 他们的
results indicate that registration leads to an increase in profits and investments for
Vietnamese SMEs. 博利 (2018) shows that becoming formal can further increase
gross profits and the value added of switchers compared with preformalization
级别, both in the short and medium term. The present study is closest to Boly
(2018) as it uses the same dataset and empirical approach, while focusing on
analyzing the relationship between formalization and tax payments. As mentioned
previously, the majority of the existing literature focuses on the private benefits of
formalization for a firm, leaving an evidence gap on the potential social benefits,
specifically those accruing to governments.
三、. 数据
The description of the dataset used in this study parallels that in Boly
(2018), restricted to informal and switching firms. The dataset comes from SME
surveys conducted in Viet Nam in 2005, 2007, 2009, 2011, 和 2013. The surveys,
which were conducted by the Central Institute for Economic Management and the
University of Copenhagen, cover about 2,500 firms in each year. They were carried
out in 10 locations in the cities of Ha Noi and Hai Phong, in Ho Chi Minh City, 和
in the rural provinces of Ha Tay, Khanh Hoa, Lam Dong, Long An, Nghe An, Phu
Tho, and Quang Nam.
The population of nonstate manufacturing enterprises was based on two data
sources from the General Statistics Office of Viet Nam (GSO): the Establishment
Census 2002 (GSO 2004) and the Industrial Survey 2004–2006 (GSO 2008). A
representative sample of registered household and nonhousehold firms was drawn
from this population, using a stratified sampling procedure. The aim was to ensure
the inclusion of an adequate number of enterprises in each province with different
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
144 Asian Development Review
ownership forms. For reasons of implementation, the survey was confined to
specific areas in each province or city. 此外, the GSO enterprise census
focused only on “visible” firms, which are those with fixed professional premises.
Informal household firms were included in the SME surveys based on
random onsite identification within the survey districts observed by the enumerator.
With such an identification approach, the informal firms included in the survey
are those operating alongside officially registered enterprises. These informal firms
may be relatively more competitive (and profitable) compared to informal firms
clustering in areas with no or very few formal firms (Rand and Torm 2012). 在这个
看待, the sample of informal firms in this study may not be fully representative of
the informal sector as a whole in Viet Nam.
Despite the aforementioned weakness, my dataset remains unique by the
number of survey years (5), number of firms, and focus on the informal sector. 我
restricted my sample to firms with at least two observations. I also excluded firms
that were formal when initially entering the sample, given that my interest is in
informal firms and whether they pay more taxes after formalization. The restricted
sample is dominated by informal nonswitchers, which account for 66% of the total
number of firms, while switchers account for 34% of the total number of firms
(Appendix Table A1.1).6
IV. Empirical Approach
To examine the relationship between formalization and tax payments, I use
the following specification:
yit = ρDS
我
+ γ Fit + βXit + λt + μi + εit
(1)
is the dependent variable; DS
where yit
i captures firm-type fixed effects (1 如果
switchers, 0 if nonswitchers); Fit indicates whether a firm has become formal or
不是 (0 if a firm is informal, 和 1 if the firm is formal); Xit represents additional
control variables; λt denotes a full set of time dummy variables; i indexes individual
firms; and t indexes time. As specified, my approach is comparable to a difference-
in-difference approach with varying treatment years.
specification
difference-in-difference
和
nonswitchers) rests on the parallel trend assumption in tax payments before
switching. A graphical check of this assumption suggests that the parallel trend
assumption holds well between 2005 和 2007 和之间 2007 和 2009, 但
switchers
(之间
这
6I assume that once a firm becomes formal it stays formal, and I recode its formality status accordingly. 在
也就是说, I do not allow a switcher to move back to the informal sector. This applies to about 4.2% of observations,
a proportion that I consider negligible. The main justification is that once a firm enters tax authorities’ records by
acquiring a tax code, it becomes very difficult for the firm to move again into informality.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
The Effects of Formalization on SME Tax Payments in Viet Nam 145
not between 2009 和 2011. As a robustness check, I run the above specification
for different waves of the survey (see section V.C.3).
A key feature of my approach is the construction of a switcher variable
denoted by DS
我 , using the variable Fit (0 if a firm is informal, 和 1 if the firm is
formal). If a firm has shifted out of the informal sector at any time in my survey
periods, the switcher variable equals 1 for all years in which the firm has been
observed in my sample (including the years before formalization); the switcher
variable equals 0 if the firm remained informal throughout the survey periods.
这 (informal) nonswitcher group is used as control group in my regressions. 这
inclusion of firm-type fixed effects in my main regressions (using dummy variable
DS
我 ) enables me to account for time-invariant heterogeneity between nonswitching
and switching firms. 因此, the variable Fit, which takes a value of 1 only for
switching firms after they have formalized, picks up the net effects of formalization.
然而, a known limitation of the fixed-effects approach is that endogeneity due
to time-varying omitted variables is still present, although the bias gets smaller
than with cross-sectional data. I therefore discuss robustness to endogeneity in
section V.C.2.
In addition to the previously mentioned variables, I include several control
variables that could affect firms’ decisions regarding tax payments. These control
variables are summarized in Appendix Table A1.2 for the pooled sample and by
firm type.7 The control variables include (我) gender of the owner or manager (1 如果
male, 0 否则); (二) education level of the owner or manager (0 if secondary
school has not been completed, 1 否则) to proxy for the owner’s or manager’s
人力资本; (三、) firm’s previous performance using previous year’s gross profits;
(四号) number of regular full-time employees (in logarithmic form), as well as the
square, to control for firm-size effects; (v) whether or not the firm holds a certificate
of land use rights to proxy for property rights; (六) government inspections (0 如果
the firm has not been subject to inspections in a given year, 1 否则); 和
(七) dummy variables to control for location and time factors.
V. 结果
After briefly discussing some summary statistics, I present results on the
relationship between formalization and total tax payments, my main variable of
兴趣, using a Tobit regression that considers both the binary participation
decision and the amount paid.8
7See also Rand and Torm (2012).
8The total tax payments variable is constructed as the sum of various taxes and fees, such as taxes on revenues,
license fees, import and export taxes, luxury good taxes, property taxes, and other taxes and fees.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
146 Asian Development Review
Average Total Tax Payments—Evolution around Formalization Year
笔记: Formalization year is equal to 0.
来源: Author’s calculations.
A.
Summary Statistics
As mentioned earlier, Appendix Table A1.2 describes the dependent
变量 (for the pooled sample) by firm type, 那是, nonswitchers and switchers
(and for switchers: 全面的, before switching, and after switching). I observe that
nonswitchers paid some form of taxes 57% 当时的, while switchers paid taxes
90% 当时的 (全面的), 83% of the time before switching, 和 97% 当时的
after switching. The differences are significant at the 1% level between nonswitchers
and switchers before switching on the one hand, and between switchers before and
after switching on the other hand.
The total tax payments made by switchers before switching (D1,778) 是
significantly higher than that of nonswitchers at the 1% 等级 (D334).9 Switchers
also pay a significantly higher amount of total taxes after joining the formal sector
(D3,792). 全面的, the average total tax payments of switchers (D2,883) 是关于 8.6
times higher than the total tax payments of nonswitchers (D334); switching from the
informal to the formal sector resulted in tax payments increasing more than twofold
from D1,778 to D3,792.
The figure uses an events-study graph to provide an illustration of the
evolution of tax payments for switchers. In this graph, the year of formalization is
set at 0 on the x-axis. Negative numbers refer to years in the preformalization period
and positive numbers to years in the postformalization period. Although there is an
9All monetary values are in real 1,000 Vietnamese dong (D).
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
The Effects of Formalization on SME Tax Payments in Viet Nam 147
桌子 1. Effects of Formalization on Total Tax Payments (Tobit)
Variables: Log (1 + 税收), (Real D1,000)
模型 1 模型 2
Switcher (from informal to formal)
Switcher (after formalization)
Time since becoming formal (dummy, 2 years or less)
Time since becoming formal (dummy, 4 + 年)
Gender of owner or manager (female = 0, male = 1)
Owner or manager completed secondary school (no = 0, yes = 1)
Gross profits (previous year, 日志)
Firm size (日志 [1 + 就业])
Firm size squared (日志 [1 + 就业])
Share of female employees
Own land use right certificate, (no = 0, yes = 1)
Compliance inspections (no = 0, yes = 1)
持续的
观察结果
Number of panels
Time dummies included
Province dummies included
2.44***
(0.19)
2.36***
(0.21)
1.06***
(0.15)
1.39***
(0.14)
0.58***
(0.17)
0.01
(0.13)
0.21**
(0.09)
0.46***
(0.08)
2.10***
(0.43)
0.01
(0.13)
0.19
(0.14)
0.46***
(0.07)
2.10***
(0.51)
−0.38*** −0.38***
(0.12)
0.39
(0.24)
0.22*
(0.12)
0.73***
(0.10)
−3.87*** −3.94***
(0.73)
4,795
1,306
是的
是的
(0.11)
0.39
(0.24)
0.23*
(0.13)
0.68***
(0.14)
(0.93)
4,795
1,306
是的
是的
D = dong.
Notes: Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Source: Author’s calculations.
increasing trend in tax payments in the preformalization period (−8; −2), I observe
a significant jump in the short term, postformalization period (0; +2); this increase
in tax payments persists in the long term (+4; +6) compared to the preformalization
period (−8; −2).
The preliminary analysis above therefore suggests that tax payments increase
after formalization.
B.
Panel Regression
I also study the relationship between formalization and tax payments using a
random effects Tobit regression (left-censored at 0). The results in Table 1 (Model 1)
show that switchers’ total tax payments are significantly higher than nonswitchers.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
148 Asian Development Review
I therefore find heterogeneity between switching and nonswitching firms; that
is, switchers tend to pay higher taxes while in the informal sector than nonswitchers
do. This heterogeneity has been typically assumed or differenced out in most of the
previous studies on formalization.
I find that
the coefficient of
is analyzed by looking at
The amount of switchers’ tax payments, both before and after they
(after
formalized,
formalization).
tax amounts
significantly compared to preformalization levels (Table 1, Model 1). For switchers,
the mean marginal effects of formalization on the expected value of the censored
outcome is about 93%, and the mean marginal effects of formalization on the
expected value of the truncated outcome is about 73%, controlling for province
and year fixed effects.
formalization increases switchers’
switcher
To study the effects of formalization over the short and long term, I use two
dummy variables that reflect the length of time since formalization. The first dummy
(short term) is 1 for firms that have been formal for 2 years or less, while the second
dummy (long term) is for firms that have been formal for 4 years or more.10 As can
be seen in Table 1 (Model 2), the increase in total tax payments is observed both in
the short and long term. However, the coefficient for total tax payments in the short
term (2 years or less after formalization) is significantly higher than the coefficient
for tax payments in the long term (4 or more years after formalization), suggesting
a decrease in total tax payments over time. Alternatively, the higher coefficients in
the short term for total tax payments may be capturing initial entry costs into the
formal sector.
Several other control variables are noteworthy in Table 1. First, lagged gross
profits have a positive and significant relationship with tax payments at the 1%
confidence level, indicating that more successful firms pay more taxes. Second,
firm size also has a positive and significant relationship with tax payments, likely
explained by the fact that it is more difficult for larger firms to hide their activities.
Finally, undergoing at least one compliance inspection is positively related to the
amount of total taxes.
C.
Robustness Check
In this section, I test the robustness of my results to measurement errors or
possible endogeneity.
10The time since switching to the formal sector is computed as follows. In the first survey year (2005), all
firms were informal. The first switchers are recorded in 2007, with formalization having taken place between 2005
and 2007. For all switching firms, I assume that formalization took place in the year of the survey. As a result, for
firms that were informal in 2005 but formal in 2007, the number of years since switching is 0 in 2007. For these firms
that switched in 2007, the number of years since switching becomes 2 in 2009, 4 in 2011, and 6 in 2013. The same
procedure is applied to firms that switched in 2009, 2011, or 2013.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
The Effects of Formalization on SME Tax Payments in Viet Nam 149
1.
Likelihood of Tax Payments
An advantage of the dataset used in this paper is the provision of hard
evidence on tax payments made by informal sector firms. However, asking about
tax payments through traditional survey techniques can be problematic as firms may
decide to misreport.11 Given these possible reporting errors, I conduct a robustness
check by using a dummy variable that equals 1 when tax payments are strictly
positive (see summary statistics in Appendix Table A1.2). This dummy dependent
variable reflects the binary participation decision to pay or not to pay taxes; it is
estimated using a random effects logit regression.
Table 2 shows that switchers’ likelihood of paying taxes is significantly
higher than nonswitchers (Model 1). The results also suggest that becoming formal
is positively and significantly associated with an increased likelihood to pay taxes
when looking at the coefficient of switcher (after formalization). Table 2 also shows
that an increased likelihood of paying taxes is observed both in the short and long
term (Model 2).
2.
Endogeneity12
This section analyzes the robustness of my results to potential endogeneity
of formalization, using a control function approach (Wooldridge 2015).
As a first step, I estimate a model of the endogenous explanatory variable:
Fit = 1 [βXit + ωIit + νit] = 1 [δZit + νit]
(2)
where 1[.] is the binary indicator function; Fit, the dependent variable, is a dummy
variable that takes a value of 1 if a firm is formal and 0 otherwise; Xit are control
variables described earlier in section IV; Iit corresponds to a set of exogenous
variables that are omitted from equation (1) and that are partially correlated with
formalization; Zit = (Xit, Iit ); and νit is an error term.
As a second step, I compute generalized residuals, ˆrit, based on results
obtained from equation (2) as follows:
ˆrit = Fitλ
(cid:4)
(cid:3)
ˆδZit
− (1 − Fit )λ
(cid:4)
(cid:3)
− ˆδZit
(3)
where λ(.) = ϕ(.)/(cid:13)(.) is the inverse Mills ratio.
As a third and final step, I reestimate equation (1) by adding ˆrit as an
additional regressor to control for endogeneity.
To construct Iit, I take the annual provincial-level averages for the following
two binary variables: access to powered equipment (1 if with access, 0 otherwise),
11For example, the World Bank Enterprise Surveys ask about “compliance of similar firms to yourself” to
limit the threat of getting wrong responses.
12See also Boly (2018).
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
150 Asian Development Review
Table 2. Effects of Formalization on Total Tax Payments (Logit)
Variables: Dummy Variable (1 if Taxes > 0)
模型 1 模型 2
Switcher (from informal to formal)
Switcher (after formalization)
Time since becoming formal (dummy, 2 年)
Time since becoming formal (dummy, 4 + 年)
Gender of owner or manager (female = 0, male = 1)
Owner or manager completed secondary school (no = 0, yes = 1)
Gross profits (previous year, 日志)
Firm size (日志 [1 + 就业])
Firm size squared (日志 [1 + 就业])
Share of female employees
Own land use right certificate (no = 0, yes = 1)
Compliance inspections (no = 0, yes = 1)
持续的
观察结果
Number of panels
Time dummies included
Province dummies included
笔记: ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1. Source: Author’s calculations. 1.77*** (0.21) 1.72*** (0.21) 1.95*** (0.26) 3.32*** (0.50) 1.23*** (0.30) 0.02 (0.13) 0.12 (0.12) 0.33*** (0.08) 1.36*** (0.41) 0.03 (0.13) 0.10 (0.12) 0.33*** (0.08) 1.39*** (0.41) −0.29*** −0.29*** (0.11) 0.37 (0.24) 0.23* (0.12) 0.66*** (0.15) −4.07*** −4.13*** (0.82) 4,795 1,306 Yes Yes (0.11) 0.37 (0.24) 0.22* (0.13) 0.64*** (0.15) (0.82) 4,795 1,306 Yes Yes and bribe payments (1 if the firm has made any bribe payments in a given year, 0 otherwise). Here, I restrict my sample to only always-formal firms and formalized firms (i.e., switchers once they have switched), with the latter included in the year following formalization. As noted in section III, informal firms in the sample were selected based on random onsite identification in the neighborhoods of formal firms. In Viet Nam, over 80% of formal firms consider that registration is beneficial, while nearly 50% of informal firms do not see any value to it (Cling, Razafindrakoto, and Roubaud 2012). My exclusive restriction assumption is that informal firms are more likely to formalize when they can observe formal firms’ characteristics and potentially attribute those characteristics to formalization. Yet, these formal firms’ observable characteristics will not affect informal firms’ tax payment behavior. l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / d i r e c t . m i t . / e d u a d e v / a r t i c e - p d l f / / / / 3 7 1 1 4 0 1 8 4 6 7 6 3 a d e v _ a _ 0 0 1 4 4 p d . / f b y g u e s t t o n 0 7 S e p e m b e r 2 0 2 3 The Effects of Formalization on SME Tax Payments in Viet Nam 151 Table 3. Effects of Formality on Total Tax Payments and Likelihood to Pay Taxes—Control Function Approach Variables Switcher (from informal to formal) Switcher (after formalization) Time since becoming formal (dummy, 2 years) Time since becoming formal (dummy, 4 + years) Generalized residuals Gender of owner or manager (female = 0, male = 1) Owner or manager completed secondary school (no = 0, yes = 1) Gross profits (previous year, log) Firm size (log [1 + employment]) Firm size squared (log [1 + employment]) Share of female employees Own land use right certificate (no = 0, yes = 1) Compliance inspections (no = 0, yes = 1) Access to machinery by formal firms (province-level average of dummy: 0 = no, 1 = yes) Bribe paid by formal firms (province-level average of dummy: 0 = no, 1 = yes) Constant Observations Time dummies included Province dummies included Number of panels Log Tax (Real D1,000), Tobit Logit (1 if Taxes > 0)
(1)
2.36***
(0.19)
1.06***
(0.14)
0.00
(0.17)
0.01
(0.14)
0.19*
(0.10)
0.46***
(0.09)
2.10***
(0.43)
−0.38***
(0.11)
0.39
(0.27)
0.22*
(0.12)
0.73***
(0.16)
(2)
2.45***
(0.19)
1.44***
(0.18)
0.62***
(0.22)
−0.07
(0.17)
0.01
(0.11)
0.21*
(0.12)
0.46***
(0.08)
2.11***
(0.45)
−0.38***
(0.12)
0.39*
(0.24)
0.23*
(0.14)
0.68***
(0.13)
(1)
0.22***
(0.02)
0.06***
(0.02)
0.03
(0.02)
0.01
(0.02)
0.01
(0.01)
0.04***
(0.01)
0.19***
(0.05)
−0.04***
(0.01)
0.05*
(0.03)
0.03*
(0.01)
0.08***
(0.02)
(2)
0.23***
(0.02)
0.10***
(0.02)
0.02
(0.02)
0.02
(0.02)
0.01
(0.01)
0.01
(0.01)
0.04***
(0.01)
0.20***
(0.05)
−0.04***
(0.01)
0.05*
(0.03)
0.03
(0.02)
0.08***
(0.02)
正式的
(No = 0,
Yes = 1),
Probit
−0.12*
(0.07)
0.38***
(0.06)
0.35***
(0.06)
1.01***
(0.22)
−0.16***
(0.05)
−0.28**
(0.12)
0.01
(0.06)
−0.04
(0.06)
8.70***
(0.91)
−0.70***
(0.12)
−13.38***
(0.93)
4,795
是的
不
−3.87***
(0.92)
4,795
是的
是的
1,306
−3.94***
(0.82)
4,795
是的
是的
1,306
−0.28***
(0.10)
4,795
是的
是的
1,306
−0.28***
(0.09)
4,795
是的
是的
1,306
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
D = dong.
Notes: Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses; ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Source: Author’s calculations
The results of the first-step regression in the first columns of Table 3 (Formal,
Probit) indicate that bribes paid by a formal firm have a negative and significant
effect on the likelihood of formalization, while access to powered equipment has
152 Asian Development Review
a positive and significant effect. As a result, Iit fulfills a requirement of the control
function approach that at least one exogenous variable that is omitted from equation
(1) be partially correlated with the dependent variable in equation (2).
The results of the third step (in the control function approach described
above) are also presented in Table 3, both for the total tax amount and the likelihood
to pay tax. They suggest that endogeneity is not an issue. This provides supportive
evidence that formalization can have a positive effect on switchers’ total tax
payments and that this effect can persist over time for the amount paid but not the
likelihood to pay tax.
3.
Unbalanced Panel
This paper uses an unbalanced panel, which includes only firms with at
least two observations. However, if firms that remain informal are more likely to
drop out of the panel (as formalized firms are more visible and easier to locate
in subsequent rounds), then this would bias the estimates derived from firms that
remain in the panel. As a first robustness check to the unbalanced panel issue, I run
regressions using the full sample, or the sample of firms with at least three, four, or
five observations. In the second check, I keep firms with at least two observations
but vary the number of survey waves, starting with the first two waves in 2005 and
2007.
In all cases, the full model (including controls) is estimated. However, in
Appendix Table A2.1 (varying sample size) and Appendix Table A2.2 (varying
number of waves), I present the coefficients for only the variables switcher (from
informal to formal) and switcher (after formalization) to save space. My results
show that switching firms are different from informal nonswitchers and that the
effect of formalization is positive and significant at conventional levels for all
samples.
D.
Discussion
To explore where the increase in tax payments after formalization comes
from, I make a distinction between revenue taxes and other taxes, with the latter
obtained by excluding revenue taxes from total tax payments. Such a distinction is
motivated by the difficulty to monitor and collect income taxes compared with other
types of taxes such as license fees or import and export taxes. This difficulty partly
explains the use of presumptive taxes for taxing informal sector activities (Joshi,
Prichard, and Heady 2014; Dube and Casale 2016).
Regression analysis indicates that both the likelihood of payments and the
amount paid in revenue-related taxes and other taxes by switchers are significantly
higher after formalization (Appendix Table A2.3). However, a large share of
additional taxes after formalization appears to come from other types of taxes,
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
The Effects of Formalization on SME Tax Payments in Viet Nam 153
not revenue-related taxes. Indeed, switchers report only a small increase in revenue
taxes paid before and after switching, based on the sample overall average (D1,152
before switching and D1,175 after switching); while other tax payments appear
to increase significantly at more than double the amount paid in revenue-related
taxes (D625 before switching and D2,616 after switching). Such a result could
suggest that some firms formalize when they realize that in order to start importing
or exporting, they need a tax identification number to make subsequent trade-
related tax payments. To some extent, these results also confirm that revenue-related
taxes can be challenging to collect, even after formalization, compared with other
types of taxes such as license fees or import and export taxes. Arguably, collecting
trade taxes mainly requires being able to control trade flows at major entry points
(e.g., ports, airports, or land borders), while collecting income or sales taxes
requires major investments in enforcement and compliance structures throughout
the entire economy.
Overall compliance with tax obligations is another interesting aspect that
can be considered when analyzing tax payments. To obtain an estimate of the
degree of overall compliance, I compared reported total taxes paid to revenue
levels by switchers, before and after formalization. However, a precise computation
of the level of compliance would require a tax calculator, which is beyond the
scope of this paper. The results on compliance should therefore be treated with
caution.
I find that, using an overall average, the total tax-to-revenue ratio of switchers
slightly increased from 1.26% before formalization to 1.44% after formalization.13
Using fractional regression, given that the ratio of total tax to revenue is between
0 and 1, I find that the increase in the compliance level is significant at the 1%
level.14 Notably, the compliance rate of switchers, even after formalization, remains
below that of always-formal firms, which stands at 3.47% in my sample, suggesting
that switchers may still not be fully compliant with their tax obligations even after
joining the formal sector.
VI. Concluding Remarks
Using a panel dataset consisting of five waves of SME surveys in Viet Nam,
this paper analyzes the relationship between formalization and tax payments. Such
an analysis can be challenging because of potential firm heterogeneity, due to the
fact that firms choosing to formalize can have different underlying characteristics
compared with the ones that remained informal.
13These levels are in line with the lower bound of estimates (1.3%–5% of annual income) provided by
Demenet (2016, p. 40).
14The results of these calculations are available from the author upon request.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
154 Asian Development Review
To control for unobserved heterogeneity, I created dummy variables that
distinguish between two groups of firms in my sample: those that remain informal
and those that switch to the formal sector at some point. As a result, when
the variable status, which takes a value of 1 only for switching firms after they
have formalized, is included in my regression, it picks up only the net effects of
formalization on tax payments.
My results show that switching firms are different
from informal
nonswitching firms regarding total tax payments. Such heterogeneity is typically
assumed in most previous studies on formalization but not explicitly assessed. After
formalization, I observe a significant increase in the amount and likelihood of tax
payments, both in the short and long term. These results are mainly driven by a
significant increase in the payment of other types of taxes—such as license fees,
import and export taxes, and property taxes—not in the payment of revenue taxes.
Overall, my results are supportive of government efforts to reduce the size
of the informal sector by promoting formalization. Such efforts are likely to
result in additional revenues for governments, which is an important assumption
underpinning the public policy rationale for promoting formalization.
References
Basu, Arnab K., Nancy H. Chau, and Ravi Kanbur. 2010. “Turning a Blind Eye: Costly
Enforcement, Credible Commitment, and Minimum Wage Laws.” Economic Journal 120
(543): 244–69.
Boly, Amadou. 2018. “On the Short- and Medium-Term Effects of Formalisation: Panel Evidence
from Vietnam.” Journal of Development Studies 54 (4): 641–56.
Bruhn, Miriam, and David McKenzie. 2014. “Entry Regulation and the Formalization of
Microenterprises in Developing Countries.” World Bank Research Observer 29 (2):186–
201.
Cling, Jean-Pierre, Mireille Razafindrakoto, and François Roubaud. 2011. “The Informal
Economy in Viet Nam.” Ha Noi: International Labour Organization.
_____. 2012. “To Be or Not to Be Registered? Explanatory Factors behind Formalizing Non-
Farm Household Businesses in Vietnam.” Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy 17 (4): 632–
52.
De Mel, Suresh, David McKenzie, and Christopher Woodruff. 2013. “The Demand for, and
Consequences of, Formalization among Informal Firms in Sri Lanka.” American Economic
Journal: Applied Economics 5 (2): 122–50.
Demenet, Axel. 2016. “Insights into a Predominant and Dynamic Informal Sector: The Case of
Vietnam.” Economies and Finances, PSL Research University. English. https://tel.archives-
ouvertes.fr/tel-1587795.
Dube, Godwin, and Daniela Casale. 2016. “The Implementation of Informal Sector Taxation:
Evidence from Selected African Countries.” eJournal of Tax Research 14 (3): 601–23.
Fajnzylber, Pablo, William F. Maloney, and Gabriel V. Montes-Rojas. 2011. “Does Formality
Improve Micro-Firm Performance? Evidence from the Brazilian SIMPLES Program.”
Journal of Development Economics 94 (2): 262–76.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
The Effects of Formalization on SME Tax Payments in Viet Nam 155
General Statistics Office of Viet Nam (GSO). 2004. Results of Establishment Census of Vietnam
2002: Vol. 2. Business Establishments. Ha Noi: Statistical Publishing House.
_____. 2008. The Real Situation of Enterprises through the Results of Surveys Conducted in 2005,
2006, 2007. Ha Noi: Statistical Publishing House.
Henley, Andrew, G. Reza Arabsheibani, and Francisco G. Carneiro. 2009. “On Defining and
Measuring the Informal Sector: Evidence from Brazil.” World Development 37 (5): 992–
1003.
International Labour Organization. 2003. “Guidelines Concerning a Statistical Definition of
Informal Employment.” 17th International Conference of Labour Statisticians, Geneva.
Joshi, Anuradha, Wilson Prichard, and Christopher Heady. 2014. “Taxing the Informal
Economy: The Current State of Knowledge and Agendas for Future Research.” Journal
of Development Studies 50 (10): 1325–47.
Maloney, William F. 2004. “Informality Revisited.” World Development 32 (7): 1159–78.
McKenzie, David, and Seynabou Sakho. 2010. “Does It Pay Firms to Register for Taxes? The
Impact of Formality on Firm Profitability.” Journal of Development Economics 91 (1): 15–
24.
Olken, Benjamin A., and Monica Singhal. 2011. “Informal Taxation.” American Economic
Journal: Applied Economics 3 (4): 1–28.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2008. “Declaring Work
or Staying Underground: Informal Employment in Seven OECD Countries.” In OECD
Employment Outlook 2008. Paris.
Rand, John, and Nina Torm. 2012. “The Benefits of Formalization: Evidence from Vietnamese
Manufacturing SMEs.” World Development 40 (5): 983–98.
Sharma, Smriti. 2014. “Benefits of a Registration Policy for Microenterprise Performance in
India.” Small Business Economics 42 (1): 153–64.
Tedds, Lindsay M. 2010. “Keeping It Off the Books: An Empirical Investigation of Firms that
Engage in Tax Evasion.” Applied Economics 42 (19): 2459–73.
Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. 2015. “Control Function Methods in Applied Econometrics.” Journal of
Human Resources 50 (2): 420–45.
Appendix 1
Table A1.1. Frequency of Sample Firm Types
Overall
Between
Firm Type
Frequency
Percentage
Frequency
Percentage
Informal nonswitchers
Switchers (informal to formal)
Total
3,170
1,859
5,029
63
37
100
896
458
1,354
66
34
100
Source: Author’s calculations.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
156 Asian Development Review
r
e
t
f
A
g
n
i
h
c
t
i
w
S
e
r
o
f
e
B
g
n
i
h
c
t
i
w
S
)
l
a
m
r
o
F
o
t
l
a
m
r
o
f
n
I
(
s
r
e
h
c
t
i
w
S
l
l
a
r
e
v
O
s
r
e
h
c
t
i
w
s
n
o
N
D
S
n
a
e
M
N
D
S
n
a
e
M
N
D
S
n
a
e
M
N
D
S
n
a
e
M
N
e
p
y
T
m
r
i
F
y
b
s
e
l
b
a
i
r
a
V
t
n
e
d
n
e
p
e
d
n
I
d
n
a
t
n
e
d
n
e
p
e
D
f
o
s
c
i
t
s
i
t
a
t
S
y
r
a
m
m
u
S
.
2
.
1
A
e
l
b
a
T
s
e
l
b
a
i
r
a
V
t
n
e
d
n
e
p
e
D
3
1
1
1
1
,
6
2
1
0
.
2
9
7
3
,
9
6
9
0
.
2
3
4
2
3
4
2
7
6
,
5
3
3
3
.
0
8
7
7
,
1
4
3
8
.
0
2
3
4
2
3
4
3
5
4
,
7
2
9
1
.
0
3
8
8
,
2
2
0
9
.
0
2
3
4
2
3
4
0
3
0
,
1
5
7
3
.
0
9
6
5
.
0
9
.
3
3
3
4
7
8
4
7
8
,
0
>
s
e
X
A
t
我
A
t
哦
t
F
我
1
(
s
e
X
A
t
我
A
t
哦
t
y
米
米
你
D
)
0
0
0
,
1
D
我
A
e
r
(
d
我
A
p
s
e
X
A
t
我
A
t
哦
时间
0
0
4
0
.
1
2
7
0
.
2
3
4
5
0
4
.
0
8
4
7
.
0
2
3
4
1
5
3
.
0
3
3
7
.
0
2
3
4
8
8
3
.
0
9
7
6
.
0
6
3
4
0
.
4
7
5
0
.
2
3
4
6
6
4
.
0
4
6
4
.
0
2
3
4
6
8
3
.
0
2
5
.
0
2
3
4
3
0
4
.
0
1
9
3
.
0
5
4
8
6
6
,
1
6
9
7
5
,
2
0
6
5
.
0
6
2
0
.
5
0
4
0
.
1
7
1
6
.
3
3
3
0
.
7
9
6
0
.
2
3
4
2
3
4
2
3
4
2
3
4
6
8
1
0
1
1
,
1
8
1
,
4
4
7
6
5
.
7
1
7
2
.
0
0
4
4
.
0
9
6
0
.
7
6
2
3
.
0
1
7
6
.
0
2
3
4
2
3
4
2
3
4
3
2
4
8
1
9
,
1
6
5
5
1
,
2
5
8
4
0
.
6
7
4
2
.
0
7
3
.
0
7
3
6
.
6
8
2
3
.
0
5
8
6
.
0
2
3
4
2
3
4
2
3
4
2
3
4
6
0
0
.
3
7
5
2
.
0
8
4
3
.
0
3
1
4
.
0
4
3
7
.
0
9
3
.
3
9
0
3
,
7
2
2
8
1
,
3
2
3
3
3
0
.
1
4
2
0
.
2
3
4
7
2
4
.
0
1
8
3
.
0
2
3
4
6
6
2
.
0
6
0
3
.
0
2
3
4
5
0
2
.
0
2
3
1
.
0
4
7
8
4
7
8
4
7
8
4
7
8
4
7
8
4
7
8
4
7
8
,
0
=
e
我
A
米
e
F
(
r
e
G
A
n
A
米
r
哦
r
e
n
w
哦
F
哦
r
e
d
n
e
G
)
1
=
e
我
A
米
)
e
s
我
w
r
e
H
t
哦
0
t
n
e
d
n
e
p
e
d
n
我
y
r
A
d
n
哦
C
e
s
d
e
t
e
我
p
米
哦
C
r
e
G
A
n
A
米
r
哦
r
e
n
w
氧
)
e
s
我
w
r
e
H
t
哦
0
,
d
e
t
e
我
p
米
哦
C
F
我
1
(
我
哦
哦
H
C
s
)
]
t
n
e
米
y
哦
我
p
米
e
+
1
[
G
哦
我
(
e
z
我
s
米
r
我
F
)
r
A
e
y
s
你
哦
我
v
e
r
p
(
s
t
fi
哦
r
p
s
s
哦
r
G
,
0
=
哦
n
(
e
t
A
C
fi
我
t
r
e
C
t
H
G
我
r
e
s
你
d
n
A
我
n
w
氧
s
e
e
y
哦
我
p
米
e
e
我
A
米
e
F
F
哦
e
r
A
H
S
)
1
=
s
e
y
,
0
=
哦
n
(
s
n
哦
我
t
C
e
p
s
n
我
e
C
n
A
我
我
p
米
哦
C
)
1
=
s
e
y
s
s
哦
r
G
,
s
e
X
A
t
F
哦
s
t
n
你
哦
米
A
e
H
t
s
w
哦
H
s
e
我
乙
A
t
s
我
H
t
H
G
你
哦
H
t
我
A
.
d
e
t
你
p
米
哦
C
e
r
A
s
C
我
t
s
我
t
A
t
s
p
你
哦
r
G
e
G
A
r
e
v
A
e
H
t
e
r
哦
F
e
乙
米
r
fi
y
乙
d
e
t
A
我
你
C
我
A
C
t
s
r
fi
s
我
e
我
乙
A
我
r
A
v
H
C
A
e
F
哦
e
G
A
r
e
v
A
s
e
我
r
e
s
e
米
我
t
e
H
时间
:
s
e
t
哦
氮
.
n
哦
我
t
A
我
v
e
d
d
r
A
d
n
A
t
s
=
D
S
,
s
n
哦
我
t
A
v
r
e
s
乙
哦
F
哦
r
e
乙
米
你
n
=
氮
,
G
n
哦
d
=
D
.
s
n
哦
我
s
s
e
r
G
e
r
n
我
s
n
哦
我
t
A
米
r
哦
F
s
n
A
r
t
G
哦
我
r
我
e
H
t
e
s
你
我
,
s
e
e
y
哦
我
p
米
e
F
哦
r
e
乙
米
你
n
e
H
t
d
n
A
,
s
t
fi
哦
r
p
.
s
n
哦
我
t
A
我
你
C
我
A
C
s
’
r
哦
H
t
你
A
:
e
C
r
你
哦
S
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
The Effects of Formalization on SME Tax Payments in Viet Nam 157
附录 2
Table A2.1. Effects of Formalization on Total Tax Payments (Tobit)—Varying Sample Sizes
Variables: Log (1 + Taxes), (Real D1,000)
1
2
3
4
5
Minimum Observations in Panel
Switcher (from informal to formal)
Switcher (after formalization)
持续的
观察结果
Number of panels
Other controls
Time dummies included
Province dummies included
2.57***
(0.21)
1.12***
(0.17)
2.75***
(0.21)
0.90***
(0.19)
2.72***
(0.31)
0.75***
(0.23)
2.60***
2.31***
(0.21)
(0.18)
1.09***
1.14***
(0.20)
(0.15)
−3.29*** −3.07*** −3.63*** −4.25*** −3.48***
(0.99)
(0.94)
4,240
5,155
1,020
1,666
是的
是的
是的
是的
是的
是的
(1.31)
2,773
570
是的
是的
是的
(1.20)
3,393
731
是的
是的
是的
(0.83)
4,795
1,306
是的
是的
是的
D = dong.
Notes: Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Source: Author’s calculations.
Table A2.2. Effects of Formalization on Total Tax Payments (Tobit)—Varying
Survey Waves
Variables: Log
(1 + Taxes),
(Real D1,000)
Switcher (from
informal to
formal)
Switcher (after
formalization)
Constant
Observations
Number of
panels
Other controls
Time dummies
included
Province
2005–
2007
2005–
2009
2005–
2011
2005–
2013
2007–
2009
2007–
2011
2007–
2013
2009–
2011
2009–
2013
2011–
2013
2.71***
(0.26)
2.82***
(0.23)
2.61***
(0.20)
2.57***
(0.21)
2.45***
(0.23)
2.27***
(0.21)
2.32***
(0.21)
1.67***
(0.36)
1.77***
(0.35)
0.79
(0.59)
1.12***
(0.17)
1.54***
(0.14)
1.31***
(0.18)
1.07***
2.40***
(0.57)
(0.20)
−4.23*** −3.67*** −3.81*** −3.07*** −6.67*** −6.04*** −4.41*** −6.40*** −4.43*** −2.35
(1.45)
(1.33)
1,778
1,962
970
1,075
(1.17)
2,128
1,203
(0.83)
4,795
1,306
(1.01)
3,979
1,306
(0.95)
3,017
1,204
(1.06)
3,906
1,305
(0.87)
3,090
1,305
(1.18)
2,833
1,157
(1.12)
2,017
1,157
1.58***
(0.17)
1.90***
(0.23)
1.34***
(0.17)
1.99***
(0.30)
2.32***
(0.33)
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
dummies
included
D = dong.
Notes: Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Source: Author’s calculations.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
7
1
1
4
0
1
8
4
6
7
6
3
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
4
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
158 Asian Development Review
Table A2.3. Effects of Formalization on Revenue and Other Tax Payments
Revenue-Related Taxes
Other Taxes
Variables
Switcher (after formalization)
Gender of owner or manager (female = 0,
male = 1)
Owner or manager completed secondary school
(1 if completed, 0 otherwise)
Gross profits (previous year)
Firm size (log [1 + employment])
Firm size squared (log [1 + employment])
Share of female employees
Own land use right certificate (no = 0, yes = 1)
Compliance inspections (no = 0, yes = 1)
Constant
Observations
Number of panels
Time dummies included
Province dummies included
Tobit
4.52***
(0.76)
−0.64
(0.79)
0.30
(0.62)
1.26***
(0.40)
8.78***
(2.65)
−1.50***
(0.57)
−0.40
(1.18)
−0.53
(0.57)
0.65
(0.76)
−20.96***
(4.66)
1,744
432
Yes
Yes
Logit (1 if
Taxes > 0)
1.01***
(0.23)
−0.15
(0.17)
0.05
(0.15)
0.28**
(0.11)
1.88***
(0.58)
−0.32***
(0.12)
−0.11
(0.28)
−0.09
(0.17)
0.15
(0.17)
−4.53***
(1.20)
1,744
432
是的
是的
Tobit
1.60***
(0.19)
0.03
(0.13)
0.23
(0.14)
0.35***
(0.09)
2.76***
(0.61)
−0.55***
(0.14)
−0.08
(0.28)
−0.20
(0.12)
0.36***
(0.13)
−1.93**
(0.93)
1,744
432
是的
是的
Logit (1 如果
Taxes > 0)
3.19***
(0.45)
0.36
(0.27)
−0.07
(0.28)
0.31**
(0.13)
3.46***
(0.86)
−0.75***
(0.19)
−0.01
(0.57)
−0.26
(0.27)
0.67**
(0.30)
−4.19***
(1.54)
1,744
432
是的
是的
Notes: Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1. Source: Author’s calculations. l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / d i r e c t . m i t . / e d u a d e v / a r t i c e - p d l f / / / / 3 7 1 1 4 0 1 8 4 6 7 6 3 a d e v _ a _ 0 0 1 4 4 p d / . f b y g u e s t t o n 0 7 S e p e m b e r 2 0 2 3