TEACHER MOBILITY, SCHOOL
SEGREGATION, AND PAY-BASED
POLICIES TO LEVEL THE
PLAYING FIELD
Charles T. Clotfelter
Sanford School of Public Policy
杜克大学
达勒姆, NC 27708
charles.clotfelter@duke.edu
Helen F. Ladd
(corresponding author)
Sanford School of Public Policy
杜克大学
达勒姆, NC 27708
hladd@duke.edu
Jacob L. Vigdor
Sanford School of Public Policy
杜克大学
达勒姆, NC 27708
jacob.vigdor@duke.edu
抽象的
Research has consistently shown that teacher qual-
ity is distributed very unevenly among schools, 到
clear disadvantage of minority students and those from
low-income families. Using North Carolina data on
the length of time individual teachers remain in their
学校, we examine the potential for using salary dif-
ferentials to overcome this pattern. We conclude that
salary differentials are a far less effective tool for retain-
ing teachers with strong preservice qualifications than
for retaining other teachers in schools with high propor-
tions of minority students. Consequently large salary
differences would be needed to level the playing field
when schools are segregated. This conclusion reflects
our finding that teachers with stronger qualifications are
both more responsive to the racial and socioeconomic
mix of a school’s students and less responsive to salary
than are their less-qualified counterparts when making
decisions about remaining in their current school, mov-
ing to another school or district, or leaving the teaching
职业.
C(西德:2) 2011 Association for Education Finance and Policy
399
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
F
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
A
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
F
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
介绍
1.
Public schools that are segregated by the race or socioeconomic status of their
students raise many educational and societal concerns. Of central interest
for this article is that such segregation is typically associated with an uneven
distribution of resources, the most important of which is teacher quality (作为
measured here by teacher qualifications) across schools. Schools with large
proportions of nonwhite or low-income students tend to have teachers with
far weaker qualifications than those in schools serving whiter or more affluent
学生 (Betts, Rueben, and Danenberg 2000; Lankford, Loeb, and Wyckoff
2002; Clotfelter, Ladd, and Vigdor 2006, 2007). This well-documented pattern
largely reflects the operation of a teacher labor market in which the distribution
of teachers across schools is determined not only by state or district policies
but also by the preferences of teachers.
For the purposes of this study, we define an equitable distribution of
teachers as one in which students of different racial and economic groups have
equal access to teachers with strong qualifications.1 This input-based definition
of equity is far less demanding than an outcome-based equity measure, 哪个
might well require that disadvantaged groups, often challenging to teach, 有
access to teachers with even stronger qualifications than those available to
other students (see Ladd 2008 and also Roemer 1998 in a broader policy
语境). 尽管如此, given the current uneven distribution of teachers in the
美国, attaining a level playing field even in our more limited sense
still represents a challenging equity goal.
One way to assure an equitable distribution of teachers would be for a state
or district to require that students of different racial and economic groups be
evenly distributed across schools. 在这种情况下, members of each student group
would automatically have equal access to teachers with strong qualifications at
the school level.2 Although the school desegregation plans that were introduced
starting in the late 1960s pushed many districts in that direction with respect
to race, the Supreme Court’s 2007 decision in Parents Involved in Community
Schools v. Seattle School District No. 1, 551 我们. 701, has ruled out the explicit
1.
Throughout, we use the expressions “teachers with strong qualifications” or “strong teachers” rather
than the more felicitous phrase “highly qualified teacher” so as not to confound our concept with
that embedded in the federal No Child Left Behind legislation, which requires that all teachers be
highly qualified but which in practice allows states to water down the requirement for many of
their established teachers. Ideally one might prefer a more encompassing but difficult to observe
construct of teacher quality. For reasons we discuss further below, we take the more pragmatic
approach of focusing on teacher qualifications.
2. This even distribution of students across schools, 然而, would still not assure equal access
to quality teachers across student groups within schools at the classroom level to the extent that
classrooms are segregated. Clotfelter, Ladd, and Vigdor (2003, 2008) document for North Carolina
that at the elementary level, most of the racial segregation is between, not within, 学校. 在
high school level, within-school segregation plays a far larger role.
400
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
/
F
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
A
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
use of the race of a student in assigning students to schools. The use of
socioeconomic rather than racial measures for the purposes of school balance
would address this legal hurdle. It would not, 然而, address the political
challenge posed by middle-class parents who tend to be highly protective
of their middle-class schools and strongly resistant to efforts to move their
children to schools with many minority or low-income students.3
In light of these obstacles, an alternative approach for promoting an equi-
table distribution of teachers would be for states or districts to pursue strate-
gies designed to counter what many teachers may view as the difficult working
conditions associated with large proportions of educationally disadvantaged
学生. Policy makers could, 例如, invest in other components of
the working conditions in those schools, such as school safety or the quality
of school leadership (Milanowski et al. 2009; Ladd forthcoming). 其他
战略, and the one of central interest for this study, is for policy makers to
use salary differentials to help schools serving disadvantaged students attract
and retain teachers with strong qualifications. The success of such a strategy
depends largely on how responsive teachers are to salary differentials on the
one hand and to school demographic characteristics on the other as they make
their job market decisions.
We use longitudinal data for teachers in North Carolina to examine
these responses, with particular attention to the differential responses of
teachers with strong qualifications compared to those with average qualifi-
阳离子. Specifically, we estimate probit models to examine how salary af-
fects the ability of schools to fill vacancies with strong teachers, 和我们
estimate competing risk hazard models to determine how both salary and
school demographics affect teachers’ decisions to leave their current schools.
The results permit us to estimate the magnitudes of the salary differentials
that would be required to offset specified differences in segregation across
学校.
As discussed below, this research follows in a long tradition of studies that
examine the determinants of teacher mobility. The research reported here is
enriched by the following components. First is our explicit attention to whether
teachers with strong qualifications respond more or less strongly than other
teachers to salary incentives and to the demographic characteristics of schools.
Second is our detailed modeling of salary differentials that take account of the
local nature of many teacher labor markets. Third is our examination of teacher
movement at all three levels of schooling. Fourth is our ability to supplement
3. A clear example emerges in Wake County, North Carolina, which until recently served as a model
for socioeconomic balancing of its schools. The recent election of a new school board majority
openly opposed to busing to achieve socioeconomic balance now threatens that system.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
F
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
A
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
401
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
our basic analysis of responses to salary differentials with a difference-in-
differences analysis of two specific policy interventions that include financial
激励措施. One of these is a program used in two of the state’s districts
designed to attract or retain teachers in hard-to-staff schools, and the other is
a short-lived statewide bonus program for selected teachers at low-performing
middle and high schools.
2. THE TEACHER LABOR MARKET
Like those for many occupations, the labor market for teachers in this country
operates largely as a set of loosely connected regional or local labor markets.
The market for teachers differs from the typical labor market, 然而, 在一个
number of ways, the most important of which relates to salaries. In the typical
labor market, competitive pressures would force employers offering jobs with
poor working conditions to pay higher salaries than other employers to attract
equally qualified workers. Public schools, 相比之下, are typically bound by
contracts within districts that stipulate specific salary levels for teachers with a
given set of credentials. To the extent that teachers with strong qualifications
prefer to teach in schools with higher-achieving, more affluent, and whiter
student bodies, schools with more disadvantaged students find it difficult to
attract and retain those teachers. Although not all teachers have such prefer-
恩塞斯, studies dating back to Becker (1952) indicate that many do.
The gravitation of teachers with strong qualifications away from schools
serving disadvantaged students to those serving more advantaged students
generates potentially large inequities across schools. This sorting process con-
sists of three identifiable processes: attrition (teachers leaving the profession),
movement (teachers changing schools, either within or across districts), 并重新-
placement (schools filling vacancies). Much has been written about the first two
of these, and we build on that literature by estimating hazard models of teacher
departures from their current schools. The third process, in which schools fill
vacancies, has received comparatively little attention, but it deserves to be exam-
ined because schools are not equally successful in attracting desirable teachers.
Examining these three processes elucidates not only how teacher labor mar-
kets lead to inequities in the matching of teachers to students in the public
schools but also the potential for salary policies to counteract these processes.
Our study builds on a substantial empirical literature that can be summa-
rized by two major conclusions.
1. 教师, like most other people, respond to financial incentives in deciding where
去工作. When working conditions are controlled for, the evidence shows
that teachers are attracted to positions with higher salaries and are more
402
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
F
/
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
A
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
F
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
inclined to leave their current post or to leave teaching altogether when
alternative salaries are higher. Thus higher teacher salaries in their current
positions tend to reduce attrition rates, and attrition is sensitive to wage
differences between teacher and nonteacher salaries.4 Teachers with the
best prospects outside teaching are generally most likely to leave teaching.
尤其, higher exit rates from the profession typically emerge for
teachers with high scores on achievement tests and for math and science
teachers than for other types of teachers who presumably have fewer good
alternatives.5
2. Teachers care about certain nonwage aspects of their jobs. As we have already
著名的, social science research going back at least fifty years suggests that
教师, by and large, prefer to work in schools with students who are high
achieving, affluent, and white.6 In studies of teacher attrition, these pref-
erences reveal themselves directly through the estimated effect of certain
school characteristics, and they also show up in comparisons of the origin
and destination schools between which teachers transfer. Racial composi-
tion is the school characteristic most consistently associated with teacher
mobility: teachers more often leave schools with higher concentrations of
nonwhite students, with a greater response among white than nonwhite
teachers.7 Particularly compelling evidence of teacher sorting by the racial
4.
5.
看, 例如, Murnane and Olsen 1989, 1990; Mont and Rees 1996; Podgursky, Monroe, 和
沃森 2004; Krieg 2006; and Reed, Rueben, and Barbour 2006. For the effect of nonteacher
salaries, see Baugh and Stone 1982; Rickman and Parker 1990; and Dolton and van der Klaauw
1995. Gritz and Theobald (1996) and Imazeki (2005) incorporate teacher salaries in both the current
and alternative districts, as well as nonteacher salaries. The former study finds significant effects in
most specifications for nonteacher salaries. The latter includes both current and expected teacher
salaries in a teacher’s own district and neighboring ones, as well as average nonteaching salaries in
the local area. It finds significant wage effects for current and expected teacher salaries and relative
teacher salaries for women, but no effects for men or women associated with nonteaching salaries.
See Murnane and Olsen 1990; Lankford, Loeb, and Wyckoff 2002; and Podgursky, Monroe, 和
沃森 2004. Stinebrickner (1998) finds that teachers with bachelor’s degrees in science were more
likely to quit, and Imazeki (2005) observes higher transfer rates among women teaching math and
special education. 相比之下, Krieg (2006) finds that highly effective female teachers, 测量的
by a long history of raising test scores, were less likely to quit.
6. Hollingshead (1949, p. 171) 报道, “Because the academic teachers believe that college preparatory
students have more ability, are more interested, and do better work than those in the general course,
they prefer to teach the former group.” See also Becker 1952.
7. Greenberg and McCall (1974, 桌子 3) show that teachers who changed schools within the San
Diego school district generally ended up in a school with a smaller proportion of minority students.
Lankford, Loeb, and Wyckoff (2002, 桌子 10) for New York and Hanushek, Kain, and Rivkin (2004,
桌子 4) for Texas show that this was also true for moves between districts. 同样地, Hanushek,
Kain, and Rivkin (2004) and Falch and Strom (2005) find that higher concentrations of minority
students were associated with higher rates of attrition. Scafidi, Sjoquist, and Stinebrickner (2007)
find both transfers and exits to be higher from predominantly black schools in Georgia for nonblack
教师. In her study of Wisconsin teachers, Imazeki (2005) finds this aversion only for exits from
教学, and then only by white male teachers. Boyd et al. (2005) find that white and Hispanic
teachers were more likely to quit or transfer from New York City elementary schools with lower
proportions of white students.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
/
F
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
A
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
403
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
mix of a school’s students emerges from a recent study of how teachers re-
sponded to the resegregation of schools associated with the end of student
busing in Charlotte, North Carolina (Jackson 2009).
Evidence also supports the view that teachers prefer to teach high-achieving
students.8 Feng and Sass (2008) find that effective teachers, 测量的
by a history of raising students’ test scores, are more likely to leave schools
where other teachers are generally less effective. Less strong is the evidence
for reluctance to teach low-income students. Although comparisons of ori-
gin and destination schools show that teachers tend to move to schools with
students from more affluent families, the independent effect of income is
often not confirmed statistically in equations that also include the racial
mix of a school’s students.9
An obvious policy response to these two stylized facts would be to use
salary differentials to offset the effect of racial composition, or other student
特征, on the perceived desirability of schools as workplaces. 康姆-
pensation policy, 然而, may or may not be a practical tool for equalizing
teacher quality across schools. 一方面, teachers may differ in their sensi-
tivity to working conditions and salary. To the extent that teachers with strong
qualifications are less responsive to salary and more responsive to student de-
mographics than other teachers, 例如, salary differentials might reduce
the overall rate of turnover at disadvantaged schools but do little to equalize
the proportion of high-quality teachers across schools. For another, salary dif-
ferentials may be more powerful tools for reducing exits from the teaching
profession than for altering the distribution of teachers across workplaces.
Hence the power of salary differentials to promote an equitable distribution of
teachers is an empirical question.
8.
In comparisons of origin and destination schools, Greenberg and McCall (1974, 桌子 3) 和
Hanushek, Kain, and Rivkin (2004) show that teachers moved from less to more able student
身体, as measured by average standardized test scores. Evidence of this preference also appears
in two multivariate studies of attrition—Mont and Rees 1996 和, for female teachers only, Krieg
2006. Clotfelter et al. (2004) find that the rate of exit from low-performing schools increased with
the advent of North Carolina’s assessment program, one that exposed teachers in low-rated schools
to fewer rewards and the prospect of punitive policies. Using data for New York City, Boyd et al.
(2008) find that teachers in low-performing schools were more likely to leave than those in other
学校.
9. See Greenberg and McCall 1974 (桌子 3) and Hanushek, Kain, and Rivkin 2004 (桌子 4). In partic-
他们是, hazard models estimated by Imazeki (2005) and Krieg (2006) obtain statistically insignificant
coefficients for percent of students receiving free lunch, and Reed, Rueben, and Barbour (2006)
obtain a negative coefficient. Note that these insignificant coefficients are not inconsistent with the
observation that teachers tend to move from poorer to richer schools because of the typically high
correlation between poverty and minority enrollment. There is also evidence that teachers are more
likely to quit when their classes are large (Mont and Rees 1996) or when they do not feel successful
or supported by school administrators (Johnson and Birkeland 2003).
404
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
F
/
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
A
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
3. MAIN CONSTRUCTS AND BASIC EMPIRICAL PATTERNS
We use North Carolina data to examine teacher mobility over the period 1995–
2004, with attention to all three levels of schooling. Before describing the
general patterns in the data, we discuss three constructs that are central to
our empirical analysis: disadvantaged students, qualifications of teachers, 和
teacher pay, with attention to what they mean in North Carolina, a state with
多于 9 million people and diverse geographic areas that range from the
coast through the Piedmont in the center to mountains in the west.10
Student Disadvantage
Throughout the analysis, we use as our two proxies of student disadvantage
at the school level the percent of students who are nonwhite and the percent
who are eligible for the federal free lunch program. Although not all nonwhite
students are educationally disadvantaged, historical patterns of discrimination,
limited family wealth or income, and the fact that some are recent immigrants
put many in that category. Most of the nonwhite students in North Carolina
are African American, although some are American Indian, and an increasing
number are Hispanic. Eligibility for free lunch, which is limited to families
with income below 130 percent of the poverty level, serves as a common,
although admittedly imperfect, measure of family income.11
We focus on these racial and economic proxies for educational disadvan-
tage largely because data for them are available at the school level. The reader
should bear in mind, 然而, that they are at best proxy measures for a
broader set of measures of student disadvantage that could well influence
teachers’ perceptions about a school’s working conditions. 基于数据
这 2000 人口普查, 桌子 1 reports correlations between various family or student
characteristics across North Carolina’s one hundred counties (whose bound-
aries are coterminous with school districts in most cases). The poverty rate for
children is positively correlated with the nonwhite percent of the population,
but the correlation is only 0.67 because the counties in the mountain region
tend to be poor but white, while rural coastal and Piedmont areas are poor
but nonwhite. Most striking are the high correlations between poverty and the
nonwhite share on the one hand and the fraction of single parent households
10. See the appendix for detailed explanations of how we constructed the variables.
11. Because low-income high school students tend to be less willing to participate in the subsidized
lunch program than their younger counterparts, the percentages are not directly comparable across
levels of schooling (Gleason 1995). For that reason, whenever we use a single free lunch measure for
all schools, we normalize it based on the means and standard deviations for each level of schooling.
因此, A 1 standard deviation difference at the elementary level represents a somewhat larger
difference in the actual percentage of students on free lunch than at either the middle or the high
school levels. 为了 2004, the means (standard deviations) in percents across schools were: elementary
45.7 (21.5); 中间 41.1 (18.1); high school 29.1 (29.8).
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
/
F
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
A
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
405
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
桌子 1. Correlations between Measures of Population Characteristics (百分比), North Carolina Counties
Nonwhite
(包括
Hispanic)
Poor
(Percent of
Children in
Poor Households)
低的
教育
(Less Than
中学)
高的
教育
(More Than
大学)
Single Parent
with Children
under Age 18
Nonwhite
1
Poor
0.67
0.67
1
0.28
0.55
−0.16
−0.47
0.89
0.64
来源: Calculated by authors based on data from the 2000 我们. 人口普查.
在另一. With only one parent at home, and one that may well be working,
children in such families are likely to receive less educational support at home
than are those in more advantaged families. Thus an apparent aversion of
teachers to either the racial or economic (或两者) characteristics of students
could in fact represent an aversion to other characteristics of the students that
are correlated with the ones we measure.12
Qualifications of Teachers
We use four measurable qualifications of teachers as proxies for teacher quality.
The first two are preservice qualifications: teachers’ average licensure test
scores and whether they graduated from a very competitive undergraduate
机构. The other two are their years of teaching experience and whether
they are certified by the National Board. All four have been shown to be
predictive of student achievement in North Carolina and elsewhere.
Studies confirm, 例如, that teachers’ own ability or achievement,
as measured by some form of test score, whether an SAT, ACT, or teacher
licensure score, is predictive of student achievement. 的确, teachers’ test
scores are the credential that most consistently emerges as predictive of student
achievement across studies of various types (see summary in Goldhaber 2008).
The research is somewhat less clear about the predictive power of the quality of
a teacher’s undergraduate institution, as typically measured by Barron’s college
ratings. Our own research using North Carolina data confirms its predictive
power at the high school level but not at the elementary level (Clotfelter, Ladd,
and Vigdor 2006, 2007, 2010).
12. Because disadvantaged students tend to achieve at below-average levels, it could also represent an
aversion to teaching low-performing students. We have chosen not to include student achievement
as a separate measure of disadvantage because it is partly endogenously determined by the quality
of teachers in the schools. 此外, the racial and economic mix of students in a school may also
be correlated with other working conditions valued by teachers. Research has shown, 然而, 那
the racial characteristics of schools still emerge as significant predictors of teacher movement, 甚至
in models that control for a variety of other working conditions, such as the quality of leadership,
school safety, and resources as perceived by teachers (Ladd forthcoming).
406
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
/
F
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
A
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
With respect to years of experience, studies from a number of states con-
sistently show that, regardless of how effective they may eventually become,
teachers with no or very limited experience are far less effective at raising
student achievement than teachers with more experience (see summary in
Goldhaber 2008). Although the studies differ on the patterns beyond the first
few years of experience, it seems safe to conclude that on average, 教师
with three or more years of experience are more effective than those with less
经验. 此外, most careful studies, including several based on North
Carolina data, show that National Board–certified teachers are more effective
at raising student achievement than are those who are not certified (Goldhaber
and Anthony 2007; Clotfelter, Ladd, and Vigdor 2006, 2007, 2010). Only at
the high school level, 然而, does it appear that the process of certification
itself makes teachers more effective (Clotfelter, Ladd, and Vigdor 2010).
How we use these measures will become clear in the analysis below. Suffice
it to say at this point that for some of the analysis we treat the preservice
qualifications differently than those related to subsequent employment so as
not to confound decisions made by teachers after they enter the profession
with more exogenous measures of teacher qualifications. Not included in this
list of qualifications is whether a teacher has a master’s or other advanced
程度, because such credentials do not generally emerge as predictive of
student achievement.13
One might legitimately ask why we use teacher qualifications as proxies for
teacher effectiveness, 而不是 (as is the case in some other recent studies) A
more direct value-added measure based on gains in their students’ test scores
(例如, Hanushek et al. 2005; Goldhaber, 总的, and Player 2009). The question
is valid because variation in these four teacher qualifications explains at best
only a portion of the total variation in teacher quality as measured by gains in
student test scores (Goldhaber 2008). One answer is that the instability of the
value-added measures for individual teachers from year to year raises questions
about their reliability (Koedel and Betts 2007; Lockwood, McCaffrey, and Sass
2008). Another is that such measures can be estimated only for teachers
in grades or courses that are tested annually, which in the North Carolina
context would typically restrict the analysis to elementary schoolteachers of
math and reading. 最后, they are not well suited for teachers with little or
13. Our own research from North Carolina shows, 例如, that elementary schoolteachers who
obtain a master’s degree between one and five years into teaching are less effective on average than
other teachers (Clotfelter, Ladd, and Vigdor 2007). Presumably this pattern says more about who
decides to get a master’s degree once they start teaching than about the value of the degree itself.
As might be expected, at the high school level where subject knowledge matters more, 硕士
degrees are somewhat more positively predictive of student achievement than at the elementary
等级, but even here the effects are very small (Clotfelter, Ladd, and Vigdor 2010).
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
F
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
A
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
407
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
no experience. Given our interest in the movements of all teachers who start
teaching stints within a nine-year period at all levels of schooling, 我们有
chosen to rely on teacher qualifications that we can observe for most of them.
Teacher Pay
In contrast to many other states, North Carolina is quite centralized, 和
teacher associations have no collective bargaining powers. The state govern-
ment provides more than 60 percent of the operating funding for the state’s
学校, and there is a statewide salary schedule for teachers. Variation across
districts comes from the fact that districts can, and typically do, supplement
teacher salaries with local tax revenues. Using information on the total amount
of supplements in each district and, whenever available, more detailed infor-
mation on how they were distributed among teachers, we constructed salaries
for different types of teachers in each district for each year of our analysis.14
In 2004–5, the average local supplement across the state was about $2,500, with supplements in the two biggest districts of Charlotte and Wake close to $5,000 and the average in the rural areas of the state about $1,500.15 In our models of teacher movement, the salary for a particular teacher, specified in logarithmic form, represents her salary in her current district. As we highlight below in the context of the results, our use of observational data for salaries generates downward-biased estimates of their effects on teacher mobility.16 Although some districts, particularly the state’s large and fast-growing ur- ban districts, operate in a state and national labor market for teachers, the relevant labor market for many districts is quite local. 尤其, when existing teachers are making their decisions about remaining in or leaving their current school, the most relevant alternative salaries are those for jobs, both teaching and nonteaching, within commuting distance. We measure the alternative teaching salary available to a teacher in each district as a weighted average of the salaries of teachers with similar characteristics in the districts within a thirty-mile radius, with the weights being student enrollment in each l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / 直接的 . 米特 . / F / e d u e d p a r t i c e – p d l f / / / / / 6 3 3 9 9 1 6 8 9 2 7 9 e d p _ a _ 0 0 0 4 0 df . 来宾来访 0 7 九月 2 0 2 3 14. In general information is available only on the total supplemental payments and the number of recipients. For some districts, more detail is available on the Internet about how the supplements are distributed among teachers. 在其他情况下, we had to make reasonable assumptions about its distribution. Details are provided in the appendix. 15. The evidence suggests that some of this variation is attributable to differences in the cost of living and to salary supplements that are higher in districts with higher proportions of novice teachers, presumably used to recruit more teachers. This statement is based on Walden and Sogutlu 2001 and on our own unpublished estimates for a more recent year. We control for some of these compensating differentials in our various models by including regional fixed effects. 16. Compared with many other states, the cross-district variation in teacher salaries is small. 在 2004, 例如, the standard deviation in salaries for teachers with a bachelor of arts degree and two years of experience across the teachers in our sample was about $800, or about 3 的百分比
average salary of $27,000. 408 Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor district. We measure nonteaching salaries as the employment-weighted aver- age of salaries in all counties within a thirty-mile radius of the school district of the teacher in question. We also include a measure of the unemployment rate within the same area to capture information about the availability of jobs. 最后, we incorporate indicator variables into our models to represent salary-related incentive programs specifically designed to attract and retain teachers in hard-to-staff schools. These programs include the Equity Plus pro- grams used in two of the state’s largest districts (Charlotte-Mecklenburg and Winston-Salem) as well as a statewide bonus program that operated between 2002 和 2004. The Equity Plus programs give certain schools a variety of benefits, including additional pay for some or all of their teachers.17 The statewide bonus program, which we have described and analyzed in more de- tail elsewhere (Clotfelter, Ladd, and Vigdor 2008), 假如 $1,800 bonuses
for certified math, 科学, and special education teachers to teach in disadvan-
taged middle schools and low-performing high schools throughout the state.
Basic Patterns
The basic empirical patterns in North Carolina are consistent with the view
that teachers are inequitably distributed across schools. 数字 1 文件,
例如, the relationship between one measure of teacher quality—the
fraction of teachers whose certification test scores fall in the top quartile of
the test score distribution—and each of the two measures of disadvantage.
Although the top graph is based on all three levels of schooling, the bottom one
refers to elementary schools alone because of the limitations of that measure
for older students. Schools that have higher proportions of nonwhite students
or higher proportions of students receiving free lunches tend to have smaller
proportions of teachers with strong qualifications by this measure, a pattern
that we also document in prior research (Clotfelter, Ladd, and Vigdor 2005;
Clotfelter et al. 2007).
Also consistent with the literature that attributes some of this inequity to
differential attrition rates by school are the patterns in figure 2. The figure
depicts, by the percentage of nonwhite students in the school, the propor-
tions of teachers who had started a job in the 1994–95 school year and had
left the school by 2002–3. The two lines distinguish between teachers with
17. The program in Charlotte-Mecklenburg began in 1997–98 and has undergone several name changes
since then. The program gives signing bonuses to teachers going to a designated school, 和
experienced “master teachers” can receive up to $2,500 for teaching in such a school. The program in Winston-Salem/Forsyth began in 1999–2000. Equity Plus schools in that district are determined by the percentage of students receiving free and reduced price lunches. All teachers in the designated schools receive bonus pay equal to 20 percent of the local supplement. This bonus increases with degree and experience, typically ranges from $500 到 $1,500 per teacher, and is paid annually. l 从http下载 : / / 直接的 . 米特 . / F / e d u e d p a r t i c e – p d l f / / / / / 6 3 3 9 9 1 6 8 9 2 7 9 e d p _ a _ 0 0 0 4 0 df . 来宾来访 0 7 九月 2 0 2 3 409 TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / 直接的 . 米特 . F / / e d u e d p a r t i c e – p d l f / / / / / 6 3 3 9 9 1 6 8 9 2 7 9 e d p _ a _ 0 0 0 4 0 df . 来宾来访 0 7 九月 2 0 2 3 数字 1. Share of Teachers in Top Quartile of Test Scores by Percentages of Disadvantaged Students at the School Level, 1994–95 high test scores and those with average test scores.18 For schools serving pre- dominantly white populations (low percentages of nonwhite students), the nine-year attrition rates for teachers hover around 60 percent and appear to be nearly independent of a teacher’s licensure test score. In schools serving 18. To enhance the readability of the figure, we have collapsed schools into bins of width 0.01 (based on the school percent nonwhite). Thus the points represent groups of schools with very similar percentages of nonwhite students, not individual schools. 410 Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor Figure 2. Teacher Attrition Rates and Percent Nonwhite Students by All Schools for Top Test Quartile Teachers and Other Teachers, 1994–95 to 2002–3. (Schools are grouped into bins of width 0.01 in terms of the percent nonwhite students in the school.) overwhelmingly nonwhite student populations, attrition rates are higher over- all and show a more distinct discrepancy between teachers with test scores in the highest quartile and all others. At schools where the nonwhite proportion of students exceeds 80 百分, the attrition rates over the period for top quar- tile teachers are usually above 80 百分, while those for teachers with lower certification test scores generally fall in the 60–80 percent range. 4. THE REPLACEMENT PROCESS: FILLING VACANCIES Starting from an uneven distribution of teachers across schools, the quickest way to level the playing field would be for the schools serving disadvantaged students to fill vacancies with applicants having strong qualifications. The question of interest here is the extent to which salary might be used as a draw for such teachers. To that end, we report in table 2 four probit models of the propensity that a school will fill an open position with an applicant having each of the four qualifications predictive of higher achievement discussed above: high test scores (in the top quartile), a degree from a very competitive college, more than two years of teaching experience, and National Board certification. We note that teachers with the first two types of qualifications include both those with and without experience. 相比之下, those in the other two categories include no novice teachers, with virtually all the National Board−certified teachers (NBCTs) having several years of experience, as is consistent with the l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / 直接的 . 米特 . F / / e d u e d p a r t i c e – p d l f / / / / / 6 3 3 9 9 1 6 8 9 2 7 9 e d p _ a _ 0 0 0 4 0 压力 . f f b y g u e s t t o n 0 7 九月 2 0 2 3 411 TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY Table 2. Filling Vacancies, Probit Models, 1995–96 to 2003–4 (1) High Test Score (2) Very Competitive Undergraduate (3) Experienced (4) National Board Certification School Characteristics Middle school High school Free lunch, elementary (%) Free lunch, 中间 (%) Free lunch, high school (%) Nonwhite, K–12 (%) Building age District Characteristics Free lunch (%) Nonwhite (%) Salary: Bachelor’s degree plus 2 (ln) Alt. salary (ln) Unemployment rate 0.0270 (0.0222) 0.0492∗ (0.0198) −0.0005 (0.0004) −0.0016∗∗ (0.0006) −0.0006 (0.0006) −0.0021∗∗∗ (0.0004) −0.0001 (0.0002) 0.0012 (0.0008) −0.0040∗∗∗ (0.0007) 2.3013∗∗∗ (0.3125) 0.6725∗∗ (0.2254) −0.0208∗∗∗ (0.0045) Equity Plus (EP) Incentive Programs CM EP school −0.0344 (0.0360) CM ever EP WS EP school WS ever EP −0.0450 (0.0304) −0.0527 (0.0766) −0.0369 (0.0484) 0.0859∗∗∗ (0.0220) 0.2265∗∗∗ (0.0195) −0.0005 (0.0004) −0.0010 (0.0006) −0.0025∗∗∗ (0.0006) −0.0015∗∗∗ (0.0004) −0.0006∗ (0.0002) 0.0025∗∗ (0.0008) 0.0001 (0.0007) 4.6181∗∗∗ (0.3052) 2.2526∗∗∗ (0.2311) −0.0325∗∗∗ (0.0047) 0.0040 (0.0348) −0.1118∗∗∗ (0.0295) −0.1231 (0.0753) −0.0475 (0.0472) −0.0252 (0.0188) −0.0007 (0.0165) 0.0000 (0.0003) −0.0013∗∗ (0.0005) −0.0002 (0.0005) −0.0019∗∗∗ (0.0003) −0.0011∗∗∗ (0.0002) 0.0004 (0.0006) −0.0014∗∗ (0.0005) 1.7777∗∗∗ (0.2571) 0.2701 (0.1869) 0.0043 (0.0037) −0.0032 (0.0311) −0.1058∗∗∗ (0.0258) −0.0788 (0.0626) −0.0946∗ (0.0413) −0.1020 (0.0553) −0.1053∗ (0.0467) −0.0017 (0.0010) −0.0016 (0.0015) −0.0053∗∗ (0.0019) −0.0028∗∗ (0.0009) −0.0024∗∗∗ (0.0006) 0.0047∗∗ (0.0016) −0.0055∗∗ (0.0017) 2.7870∗∗∗ (0.7485) 0.6497 (0.5531) 0.0099 (0.0116) 0.0526 (0.0913) 0.0757 (0.0774) −0.4276 (0.2408) −0.0886 (0.1649) 氮 129,388 129,388 129,388 129,388 Notes: Controls: Log enroll (dist), rural, coastal, mountain, beach, 年, indicator for no district within in 30 miles. Union schools in 2003 were excluded due to missing data. Standard errors are in parentheses. CM = Charlotte-Mecklenburg; WS = Winston-Salem. ∗p < 0.05; ∗∗p < 0.01; ∗∗∗p < 0.001. 412 l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / d i r e c t . m i t . f / / e d u e d p a r t i c e - p d l f / / / / / 6 3 3 9 9 1 6 8 9 2 7 9 e d p _ a _ 0 0 0 4 0 p d . f f b y g u e s t t o n 0 7 S e p e m b e r 2 0 2 3 Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor requirements of that qualification. All the models were estimated based on data from 1995–96 to 2003–4 and include the variables listed in table 2 as well as others listed in the table footnote. (See appendix table A.1 for means and standard deviations.) The unit of observation is a school vacancy that is filled with a replacement teacher by year.19 Because probit coefficients are not straightforward to interpret, we begin by focusing on their signs and statistical significance, and leave to a subsequent table the policy implications of the estimated magnitudes. Emerging most clearly and consistently across all five equations are the statistically significant negative coefficients on the nonwhite percentage of the school’s students, the relatively consistent negative coefficients on the nonwhite percentage in the district, and the statistically significant positive coefficients on district salary (expressed in logarithmic form).20 These patterns imply, as expected, that the higher the nonwhite share of students in the school or the district, the harder it is for the school to fill a vacancy with a teacher having any of the specified qualifications. However, these patterns also imply that higher salaries make it easier to do so. Results for many of the other variables are more mixed across the equa- tions. Compared with elementary schools, for example, middle schools and high schools find it easier to fill vacancies with teachers having degrees from a very competitive college and possibly with high test scores. Consistent with the racial patterns for those two levels of schooling, the coefficients of the proportion of students eligible for free lunch are negative in all cases but are not always statistically significant. We also included a variable denoting the age of the building with the expectation that older schools might find it more difficult to attract teachers than newer ones with more modern amenities. As expected, the evidence is generally consistent with that expectation. Among the district-level variables, most intriguing are the results for the salaries in nearby districts and the local unemployment rate. The somewhat unexpected positive sign in the first two columns for the nearby teacher salaries (alt. salary) suggests that, holding constant the salary in the specific district, teachers with strong preservice qualifications are more attracted to schools in districts located near high-paying districts than to those in districts in geo- graphic areas with lower salaries. Our interpretation is that for some teachers 19. All the models presented here pool the three levels of schooling. We have also estimated separate models by level of schooling. The patterns do not differ much by level of schooling. Where differences emerge, we highlight them in a later footnote. In addition, we have estimated a model that examines the probability of hiring a teacher with a combination of all the strong qualifications or three of the four qualifications, but the probabilities of those combinations are too low in many cases to make the results meaningful. 20. The district salary is for a teacher with a bachelor’s degree and two years of experience. l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / d i r e c t . m i t . / / f e d u e d p a r t i c e - p d l f / / / / / 6 3 3 9 9 1 6 8 9 2 7 9 e d p _ a _ 0 0 0 4 0 p d . f f b y g u e s t t o n 0 7 S e p e m b e r 2 0 2 3 413 TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY the initial district may be the first step toward obtaining a job in the higher- paying district. The negative coefficient on the unemployment rate in those same two columns is consistent with that general story: a higher overall unem- ployment rate in the local area makes it more difficult for a school to attract a teacher with either of the strong preservice qualifications. These patterns differ from those for the chances of hiring the more experienced teachers, as shown in the final two columns. Presumably because many teachers with experience or who are board certified are already in the area, neither the alternative salary nor the unemployment rate has a statistically significant effect on the chances that such teachers will be hired.21 To infer the impact of the Equity Plus programs in the Charlotte- Mecklenburg (CM) and Winston-Salem (WS) districts, we introduce two sets of indicator variables. Each set includes a variable designating whether the school was eligible for the program in the current year (EP school) and whether the school ever participated in the program (ever EP), which controls for any per- manent unobserved difference between participating and other schools. Thus the coefficient of the “EP school” variable generates our best estimate of the treatment effect of the program. The results in table 2 show no evidence that participation in either district’s Equity Plus program in a particular year in- creased the probability that schools would recruit more teachers with strong qualifications. Although the generally negative coefficients on the “ever EP” indicators show, as expected, the greater challenges such schools face in hiring teachers with strong qualifications, none of the program-specific coefficients are statistically significant. We do not find the absence of a recruiting effect surprising, given that many prospective teachers may not expect the bonus program to be sustained over time. Table 3 spells out the salary implications of the key coefficients related to the school and district characteristics from the top two panels of table 2. The entries in each cell are the salary differences required to level the playing field between schools with the specified differences in nonwhite shares of students in the school (panel A) and in the district (panel B). For example, panel A indicates that to neutralize a difference in the nonwhite school percentage of 50 percentage points (e.g., between schools with 25 and 75 percent nonwhite shares) on the probability of hiring a teacher with a high test score, the salary would have to be 4.7 percent higher in the more nonwhite school, controlling for the district-level share. Further, the required salary needed to offset a 50 21. We have not included nonteaching salaries in this equation because the variable was missing for some of our districts in some years. In samples restricted to the districts for which we had complete data, its coefficient is only marginally significant in one model, that for hiring a teacher from a selective college, where it is negative. 414 l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / d i r e c t . m i t . / / f e d u e d p a r t i c e - p d l f / / / / / 6 3 3 9 9 1 6 8 9 2 7 9 e d p _ a _ 0 0 0 4 0 p d f . f b y g u e s t t o n 0 7 S e p e m b e r 2 0 2 3 Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor Table 3. Salary Differences Required to Level the Playing Field (Percent) Panel A Percentage Point Difference in Nonwhite Share in School High test score Undergrad very competitive Experienced NBCT teacher Panel B High test score Undergrad very competitive Experienced NBCT teacher 10 0.9 0.3 1.1 1.0 20 1.8 0.7 2.2 2.0 30 2.8 1.0 3.3 3.1 40 3.7 1.3 4.4 4.1 Percentage Point Difference in Nonwhite Share in District 10 1.8 0.0 0.8 2.0 20 3.5 0.0 1.6 4.0 30 5.4 0.1 2.4 6.1 40 7.2 0.1 3.2 8.2 50 4.7 1.6 5.5 5.2 50 9.1 0.1 4.0 10.4 percent difference in both the school and the district percentage of nonwhite students on the probability of hiring a teacher with a high test score would be the sum of the relevant entries in the two panels, or 13.8 percent. On a base salary of, say, $30,000, the required differential would amount to $4,100.22 Four observations are worth making about these entries. First, given that the required salary differentials are estimated from existing salary differentials across districts, they should be interpreted as persistent salary differences rather than as differences in the form of bonuses that apply to either a single year or a short period, as might be the case for the Equity Plus programs. The second is that we are less confident about the exact numbers for required salary differentials that are large relative to the actual variation in our sample than we are for relatively small implied salary differentials, such as those in the range of 6–8 percent.23 Nonetheless, we can be quite confident that they are big. The third is that the entries should be interpreted as upper bound estimates of the required salary differentials, because the estimated coefficients of the salary variables most likely underestimate the effect of salary on hiring decisions. That is the case because some of the interdistrict salary differences undoubtedly reflect compensating differentials for district characteristics not fully controlled for in the models, including, for example, differences in the 22. Separate estimates by level of school imply that the salary differentials would have to be highest at the high school level and lowest at the elementary level. Note in addition that it would not be correct simply to add the relevant coefficients to determine the required salary differential needed to hire a teacher with more than one of the specified qualifications because of the potential for positive correlation among them. 23. Within our sample, a 1 standard deviation in salary in any one year is about 3 percent. l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / d i r e c t . m i t . / / f e d u e d p a r t i c e - p d l f / / / / / 6 3 3 9 9 1 6 8 9 2 7 9 e d p _ a _ 0 0 0 4 0 p d f . f b y g u e s t t o n 0 7 S e p e m b e r 2 0 2 3 415 TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY cost of living. If the downward bias were as large as 25 percent, for example, unbiased estimates of the required differentials would be 25 percent smaller than those reported in table 3.24 Third, even with the downward adjustments of this magnitude, the entries suggest that salary differentials are potentially powerful tools for equalizing the ability of schools to fill vacancies with strong teachers. At the same time, the salary differentials required to neutralize the effects of large differences in concentrations of student disadvantage are likely to be far higher than the $1,800 bonus that the state legislature embedded in
its short-lived Bonus Program.
5. ATTRITION AND MOVEMENT
Once hired to work in a school, a teacher can leave the school by one of three
routes: she can leave the teaching profession, transfer to another school within
the same district, or move to another district. Because of the nature of our data,
we cannot separate those teachers who leave the profession from those who
move to another state, into the private sector, or into a charter school. Hence,
for this analysis, the option labeled “leaving teaching” in fact means leaving
the traditional North Carolina public school system.
As in the previous section, our goal is to identify the role of student de-
mographics and specific policy levers, most notably salary, in predicting these
three types of teacher moves so that we can assess the viability of compen-
satory policies to equalize rates of departure, with particular attention to the
moves of teachers with strong qualifications. Our models include a number
of teacher-level, school-level, district-level, and local area-level covariates, as
well as indicator variables by year. These covariates capture both the personal
predictors of departure, such as being a female of childbearing age, and the
local amenities or opportunity costs that might influence teacher decisions.
We model teacher choices using a discrete time, competing risk hazard
model, where the hazard rate λi (tj) is the probability that a teaching spell will
end at the close of year tj by way of exit mode i, conditional on the teacher not
having left his or her school before this period. In order to avoid the compli-
cations of dealing with left-censored observations, we restrict our analysis to
teachers who began teaching spells during the period under study—that is, be-
tween 1994–95 and 2003–4. We separately analyzed two sets of teachers, those
who had never taught before the new spell began (initial teaching spell) and
those who had previously taught before the spell began (second or later teach-
ing spell). We adopt the Cox proportional hazard model, a semi-parametric
24. We use the 25 percent figure because that is the degree of estimated bias reported in Hanushek,
Kain, and Rivkin 2004.
416
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
/
f
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
specification that is agnostic with respect to the form of the baseline hazard
function,25 and estimate a system of equations of the form:
λi(tj) = λ0i(tj) exp(X βi + μi),
where λi (tj) is the hazard rate applying to exit mode i, λ0i (tj) is the baseline
hazard, X is a matrix of teacher, school, district, and region characteristics
relevant to movement or attrition for teachers in the sample, μi is an error
term, and βi is a vector of coefficients. For 0–1 dichotomous variables, the
hazard ratio relevant to exit mode i—the estimated multiplicative impact of a
unit change on the conditional probability of a spell ending at the close of year
tj, given that the teacher has remained in the original school up to that point—
is calculated as exp(βi). Consistent with the proportional hazard model, the
impact of these covariates is assumed to be independent of the duration of the
teaching spell.
Over the period of study, we observed 48,753 teachers in their first spell
and 27,928 teachers in a later spell, some of whom overlap with the first
group. For the former teachers, we allow their first spells of teaching in the
same school to last for up to nine years, which generates a sample of 121,547
teacher-year observations. Based on all our observations of these teachers over
the sample period, the probability that a teacher in her first spell of teaching
would leave the state’s public schools in any given year is 9.4 percent. The
corresponding probability of leaving the district for another district in the state
is 6.9 percent, and the probability of switching schools within a district is 14.2
percent. For the 27,928 veterans, we follow each new spell that started during
the period 1995–96 to 2003–4, which generates a sample of 99,754 teacher-
year observations.26 The corresponding departure probabilities for this group
are 13.5 percent for leaving the profession, 4.8 percent for leaving the district,
and 10.6 percent for leaving the school for another school within the district.
Full results for our panel of teachers in their first spells are reported in
table 4 and in subsequent spells in table 5. The entries are reported as hazard
ratios, with ratios greater than one indicating that a factor makes departure
via a particular route more likely and below one less likely. In addition to the
variables of interest, we have also included indicators for the gender and race
of each teacher and a set of indicator variables for the age of the teachers,
25.
In particular, the proportional hazard specification accommodates either positive or negative du-
ration dependence. That is, the period a teacher has been in her current position could be either
positively or negatively associated with the probability that she would leave the school in the next
period.
26. There is one less year for the veteran teachers because we had to use the 1994–95 information to
determine whether the teacher was starting a new spell in the subsequent year.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
f
/
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
f
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
417
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
Table 4. Teacher Departures, by Exit Route, for Initial Teaching Spells (Hazard Ratios)
Variable
Teacher Characteristics
Female
Black
Other nonwhite
Teacher age 25–29
Teacher age 30–34
Teacher age 35–39
Teacher age 40–44
Teacher age 45–49
Teacher age 50 and over
Teacher age 25–29 ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher age 30–34 ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher age 35–39 ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher age 40–44 ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher age 45–49 ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher age 50 and over ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher Qualifications
Teacher test score—highest quartile
Undergrad college very competitive
National Board certified
Has advanced degree
Graduated NC college
Graduated bordering state college
Teacher test score—missing
School Characteristics
Middle school
High school
Free lunch eligible (%) (normalized)
Nonwhite students (%) (demeaned)
Age of school building
Building age missing
District Characteristics
Free lunch eligible (%) (demeaned)
Nonwhite students (%) (demeaned)
Enrollment (ln)
Growth rate
Rural
Coastal
Exit Route
All Exit
Routes
Leave
Teaching
Switch
Districts
Change
Schools
0.957∗∗
1.070∗∗∗
1.008
0.936∗∗∗
0.947
0.948
0.946
0.898
1.057
1.097∗∗∗
1.034
0.970
0.902
0.957
0.991
1.025∗
1.037∗∗∗
0.872∗∗
1.052∗∗
0.841∗∗∗
0.966
1.376∗∗∗
1.066∗∗∗
0.998
1.030∗∗
1.002∗∗∗
1.000
0.985
1.000
1.001
0.987
1.460
1.009
0.961∗
0.884∗∗∗
1.228∗∗∗
1.069
0.973
0.952
0.967
0.996
0.792∗∗
1.013
1.194∗∗∗
1.106
0.960
0.818∗
0.990
1.017
1.152∗∗∗
1.092∗∗∗
0.522∗∗∗
1.053
0.599∗∗∗
0.931∗∗
2.061∗∗∗
1.106∗∗∗
1.224∗∗∗
1.023
1.002∗∗∗
1.000
0.989
1.001
1.002∗∗
0.995
1.844
0.968
0.952
1.061∗
0.795∗∗∗
0.720∗∗∗
0.837∗∗∗
0.838∗
0.839
0.784
0.872
1.018
1.041
0.887
0.854
0.651∗∗
0.793
0.780
0.978
1.043
1.172
1.265∗∗∗
1.269∗∗∗
0.993
0.744∗∗∗
1.205∗∗∗
1.153∗∗∗
0.994
1.006∗∗∗
1.000
0.991
0.999
1.000
0.784∗∗∗
0.149∗
1.002
1.084∗∗
0.968
1.066∗∗
1.125∗
0.926
0.991
0.965
0.936
1.126
1.093
1.038
1.060
1.154
1.324∗
1.056
1.242
0.897∗∗∗
0.935∗∗∗
1.089
0.968
1.104∗∗∗
1.014
0.948∗
0.955∗∗
0.620∗∗∗
1.064∗∗∗
1.000
1.002∗∗∗
0.967
0.999
0.998
1.188∗∗∗
2.066
1.108∗∗∗
0.889∗∗∗
418
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
f
/
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
Table 4. Continued.
Variable
Mountain
Research university or college in county
Beach county
Labor Market Characteristics
Salary (ln) (demeaned)
Teacher salary (weighted avg.)
in surrounding districts (ln)
Local area nonteaching salary (ln)
Area unemployment rate
Equity Plus (EP) Incentive Programs†
CM EP school
CM ever EP
WS EP school
WS ever EP
Interactions with Teacher Test Score in Highest Quartile
Salary (ln) (demeaned)
Nonwhite students (school) (%) (demeaned)
Nonwhite students (district) (%) (demeaned)
Free lunch eligible (school) (%) (normalized)
Free lunch eligible (district) (%) (demeaned)
1.920∗∗∗
1.003∗∗
0.997∗∗
0.972
1.004∗∗
Interactions with Very Competitive Undergraduate College
Salary (ln) (demeaned)
Nonwhite students (school) (%) (demeaned)
Nonwhite students (district) (%) (demeaned)
Free lunch eligible (school) (%) (normalized)
Free lunch eligible (district) (%) (demeaned)
1.309
1.001
0.998
0.966
1.003
Exit Route
All Exit
Routes
Leave
Teaching
Switch
Districts
Change
Schools
0.983
1.017
1.066∗∗
0.957
1.026
1.180∗∗∗
0.224∗∗∗
0.065∗∗∗
1.371
1.035
1.113∗∗
0.989∗∗
1.012
0.982∗∗
1.035
0.970
0.844∗
0.964
0.966
1.006
0.828
0.870
7.338∗∗∗
1.005∗∗∗
0.998
0.889∗∗∗
1.005∗
0.965
0.999
1.002
0.986
0.998
1.023
0.956
0.848∗∗∗
0.158∗∗∗
2.869∗∗
1.836∗∗∗
1.009
0.648∗∗∗
1.185
0.963
0.776
0.752
0.999
1.002
1.036
1.001
1.076
1.004
0.989∗∗∗
0.929
1.012∗∗∗
0.973
1.069∗∗
1.120∗∗
0.860
1.675
0.840∗
0.986
1.053
1.074
1.081
0.899
0.737
1.002
0.994∗∗
1.047
1.002
2.267∗∗∗
1.004∗∗
0.995∗
0.976
1.002
Number of teacher-years
121,547
121,547
121,547
121,547
†CM = Charlotte-Mecklenburg; WS = Winston-Salem.
∗p < 0.05; ∗∗p < 0.01; ∗∗∗p< 0.001.
both by themselves and interacted with whether the teacher is female. These
variables control for different departure propensities by age and also among
women of childbearing age. As one might expect, female teachers in their
initial teaching spells in the 25–29 age range exhibit higher probabilities of
leaving the profession than male teachers and teachers of other ages in any
specific year, given that they have been in the school to that point. Some
of them, however, may reappear as veteran teachers starting a new spell in
a subsequent year. For both samples, females are less likely than males to
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
f
/
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
419
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
Table 5. Teacher Departures, by Exit Route, for Subsequent Teaching Spells (Hazard Ratios)
Variable
Teacher Characteristics
Female
Black
Other nonwhite
Teacher age 25–29
Teacher age 30–34
Teacher age 35–39
Teacher age 40–44
Teacher age 45–49
Teacher age 50 and over
Teacher age 25–29 ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher age 30–34 ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher age 35–39 ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher age 40–44 ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher age 45–49 ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher age 50 and over ∗ female (teacher)
Teacher Qualifications
Teacher test score—highest quartile
Undergrad college very competitive
National Board certified
Has advanced degree
Graduated NC college
Graduated bordering state college
Teacher test score—missing
School Characteristics
Middle school
High school
Free lunch eligible (%) (normalized)
Nonwhite students (%) (demeaned)
Age of school building
Building age missing
District Characteristics
Free lunch eligible (%) (demeaned)
Nonwhite students (%) (demeaned)
Enrollment (ln)
Growth rate
Rural
Coastal
Exit Route
All Exit
Routes
Leave
Teaching
Switch
Districts
Change
Schools
0.894∗
1.085∗∗∗
1.072∗
1.031
0.972
0.839∗∗∗
0.880∗
0.896∗
0.999
1.067
1.112
1.161∗∗
1.044
0.984
0.973
0.994
1.018
0.863∗∗∗
1.078∗∗∗
0.874∗∗∗
0.981
1.060∗∗∗
1.058∗∗∗
0.946∗∗∗
1.043∗∗∗
1.002∗∗∗
1.001∗∗
1.031
1.000
1.001
0.989
2.003
0.773∗∗∗
1.175∗∗∗
0.893∗∗
0.973
0.842∗∗
0.746∗∗∗
0.732∗∗∗
0.800∗∗
1.084
1.292∗∗∗
1.366∗∗∗
1.320∗∗∗
1.118
0.945
0.928
1.082∗∗∗
1.089∗∗∗
0.451∗∗∗
1.097∗∗∗
0.737∗∗∗
1.007
1.228∗∗∗
1.090∗∗∗
1.096∗∗∗
1.002
1.002∗∗
1.000
0.983
1.002
1.003∗∗
0.983
14.693∗∗∗
0.993
0.911∗∗∗
0.983
0.944
0.883
0.885∗∗∗
0.819∗∗
0.835
0.996
0.804
0.929
0.906
0.858
1.170
0.940
0.954
0.936
0.904
0.919
0.829∗∗∗
0.938∗
0.925
1.125∗∗∗
0.942∗
0.860∗∗∗
0.802∗∗∗
1.279∗∗∗
1.218∗∗∗
1.099∗∗∗
1.004∗∗∗
1.000
1.035
0.996∗
1.002
0.727∗∗∗
2.067
1.021
0.968
1.150
1.074∗∗
1.453∗∗∗
1.280∗∗
1.216∗
1.045
1.144
1.079
0.977
0.751∗∗
0.883
1.012
0.924
0.976
1.050
0.974
0.945∗∗
1.315∗∗∗
1.031
1.048∗∗
1.005
0.995
0.945∗∗
0.681∗∗∗
1.071∗∗∗
1.001
1.002∗∗∗
1.095∗∗∗
1.001
0.997∗∗
1.189∗∗∗
0.020∗∗∗
1.023
0.840∗∗∗
420
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
/
f
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
Table 5. Continued.
Variable
Mountain
Research university or college in county
Beach county
Labor Market Characteristics
Salary (ln) (demeaned)
Teacher salary (weighted avg.)
in surrounding districts (ln)
Local area nonteaching salary (ln)
Area unemployment rate
Equity Plus (EP) Incentive Programs†
CM EP school
CM ever EP
WS EP school
WS ever EP
0.976
1.017
1.080∗∗
1.171∗
0.731∗∗∗
0.971
0.992
0.945
1.080∗
0.876
0.853∗
Interactions with Teacher Test Score in Highest Quartile
Salary (ln) (demeaned)
Nonwhite students (school) (%) (demeaned)
Nonwhite students (district) (%) (demeaned)
Free lunch eligible (school) (%) (normalized)
Free lunch eligible (district) (%) (demeaned)
0.975
1.001
1.000
0.982
1.000
Interactions with Very Competitive Undergraduate College
Salary (ln) (demeaned)
Nonwhite students (school) (%) (demeaned)
Nonwhite students (district) (%) (demeaned)
Free lunch eligible (school) (%) (normalized)
Free lunch eligible (district) (%) (demeaned)
0.933
1.001
0.998
1.001
1.000
Exit Route
All Exit
Routes
Leave
Teaching
Switch
Districts
Change
Schools
1.001
1.065∗∗
1.116∗∗
1.172
0.446∗∗∗
0.687∗∗∗
0.980∗∗
0.905
1.099
1.186
0.793∗
1.266∗
1.000
1.002
0.985
0.997
0.857
0.999
1.002
0.995
0.996
1.001
0.983
0.833∗∗
0.737
1.551∗∗
1.605∗∗∗
1.023∗
0.900
1.068
0.853
0.870
0.734
1.001
1.001
0.899
1.007
1.168
1.002
1.001
1.035
1.002
0.919∗∗
0.991
1.175∗∗∗
1.199
1.155
1.124
0.990
1.095
0.963
0.918
0.611∗∗∗
0.844
1.002
0.998
1.016
1.001
1.087
1.004∗∗
0.991∗∗∗
1.004
1.003
Number of teacher-years
99,754
99,754
99,754
99,754
†CM = Charlotte-Mecklenburg; WS = Winston-Salem.
∗p < 0.05; ∗∗p < 0.01; ∗∗∗p < 0.001.
leave their current school, and black teachers are not only more likely to leave
their current school but are also more likely than white teachers to leave the
profession altogether.
Effects of Strong Qualifications
The various measures of teacher qualifications enter the models in different
ways. One measure of quality, having some experience, is included implicitly
by the estimation of separate models for initial and subsequent spells. By
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
f
/
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
f
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
421
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
definition, any teacher observed in a second or subsequent spell has at least one
year of experience and could well have many more. Consequently, consistent
with the evidence cited earlier, such teachers are likely to be more effective than
typical teachers in their first teaching spells. The two preservice qualifications
variables—having a highest quartile test score and having attended a very
competitive undergraduate institution—enter the model both directly as well
as interacted with the salary and demographic variables, so we can test for
differential responses of teachers with those qualifications.
NBCT status is included in the equations as a control variable but is not in-
teracted with other variables because teachers can select into this qualification
after they enter the teaching profession. Only those teachers who are commit-
ted to the profession are likely to undertake the rigorous process to become cer-
tified, given that the certification is not transportable to nonteaching jobs. Sim-
ilarly, many teachers select into the category of having a master’s degree after
they enter the profession with the goal of obtaining a higher salary as a teacher.
For that reason, we have included whether a teacher has an advanced degree
as an additional control variable that could affect teacher mobility. Consistent
with the selection processes just described, table 4 shows that teachers who
are board certified exhibit lower hazards of leaving their current schools than
teachers who are not board certified and that the lower hazard is attributable
primarily to their greatly reduced hazard of leaving the profession. In contrast,
teachers with advanced degrees emerge as more willing than comparable
teachers without an advanced degree to leave their current school, but they do
so primarily by changing districts. Thus their advanced degrees increase their
mobility within, but not necessarily outside, the teaching profession.
The models also include as control variables whether the teacher graduated
from a North Carolina college or a college from a bordering state. Graduation
from a North Carolina college reduces the exit hazard for a teacher both for all
types of exit and for leaving the profession, which, recall, could refer to leaving
the state.
Table 6 reports the hazard ratios of the two preservice teacher qualifica-
tions separately for the two samples of teaching spells. In each case the ratios
are relative to a “regular” teacher, defined as one who neither has a licensure
test score in the top quartile nor attended a very competitive college. For the
teachers in their initial spells, we find that the two measures of strong qual-
ifications, both separately and combined, are associated with higher overall
exit hazards, despite the fact that these teachers are less likely than regular
teachers to change schools within the district. Their higher overall exit rates
arise because of their far greater likelihood of leaving the profession. In partic-
ular, a teacher with both high test scores and a degree from a very competitive
college is more than 25 percent more likely to end a teaching spell by leaving
422
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
f
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
f
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
Table 6. Effects of Teacher Qualifications on Teacher Exits (Hazard Ratios)
All Exit
Routes
Leave
Teaching
Exit Route
Switch
Districts
Change
Schools
Panel A: Initial Teaching Spells
Has a high quartile test score
Teacher qualifications relative to regular teacher in average school
1.152∗∗
1.092∗∗
1.258∗∗
High test + very competitive college
1.025∗
1.037∗∗
1.063∗∗
Undergraduate very competitive
Panel B: Subsequent Teaching Spells
Has a high quartile test score
Teacher qualifications relative to regular teacher in average school
1.082∗∗
1.089∗∗
1.179∗∗
High test + very competitive college
Undergraduate very competitive
1.012
0.994
1.018
0.978
1.043
1.020
0.829∗∗
0.938∗
0.778∗∗
0.897∗∗
0.935∗∗
0.839∗∗
0.974
0.945∗∗
0.920∗∗
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
∗statistically significant at the .10 level; ∗∗statistically significant at the .05 level.
the profession than is a regular teacher. For the teachers in their second or
later teaching spells, in contrast, the overall exit hazards for teachers with
this combination of strong qualifications of leaving their current school are
not statistically different from those of a regular teacher. These overall exit
ratios, however, mask differential exit routes of the teachers with strong qual-
ifications. Although such teachers are about 8 percent less likely than other
teachers to end a teaching spell by moving to a different school within the same
district and about 22 percent less likely to change districts, they are about 18
percent more likely to end it by leaving the profession.
Responses to Own Salary and School Demographics
The entries in table 7 illustrate how exit hazards are affected by salaries and
by the demographic characteristics of the teachers’ schools, with particular
attention to the different response rates of regular teachers and teachers with
strong qualifications. In all cases, the salary change refers to the teacher’s
salary in her current district, assuming no change in teaching or nonteaching
salaries in the local area. Of most interest are the findings for the teachers in
their initial spells as reported in the first panel.
Consider first the simulated hazard ratios for a regular teacher of leaving
her current school by any of the three exit routes. A 10 percent increase
in salary reduces the probability that she will leave her current school in
any given year by about 14 percent (one minus the hazard ratio of 0.861).
In contrast, a 10 percentage point increase in the nonwhite students in the
school increases the probability by about 2 percent, and a 1 standard deviation
/
/
f
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
423
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
Table 7. Responses to Salary and School Demographics, by Type of Teacher (Hazard Ratios)
Exit Route
All Exit
Routes
Leave
Teaching
Switch
Districts
Change
Schools
Panel A: Initial Spells
Predicted response to a 10 percent increase in district salary (in average school)
Regular teacher
Regular teacher plus 2 qualifications
0.861∗∗
0.944∗,++
0.761∗∗
0.925∗,++
0.831∗∗
0.814∗∗
0.985
1.037
Predicted response to a 10 percentage point increase in percentage of nonwhite students in the school
Regular teacher
Regular teacher plus 2 qualifications
1.023∗∗
1.069∗∗,++
1.022∗∗
1.067∗∗,++
1.060∗∗
1.096∗∗
1.005
1.067∗∗,++
Predicted response to a 1 standard deviation increase in the percentage of free lunch students
in the school
Regular teacher
Regular teacher plus 2 qualifications
1.030∗∗
0.967,+
1.023
0.897∗∗,++
0.994
0.957
1.064∗∗
1.088
Predicted response to a 10 percentage point increase in percentage of nonwhite students in the district
Regular teacher
Regular teacher plus 2 qualifications
1.010
0.960∗∗,++
1.023∗∗
1.024
1.005
0.914∗∗,++
0.983
0.880∗∗,++
Panel B: Second or Later Spells
Predicted response to a 10 percent increase in district salary (in average school)
Regular teacher
Regular teacher plus 2 qualifications
1.016∗
1.007
1.016
1.025
0.970
0.955
1.019
1.010
Predicted response to a 10 percentage point increase in percentage of nonwhite students in the school
Regular teacher
Regular teacher plus 2 qualifications
1.022∗∗
1.045∗∗
1.024∗∗
1.015
1.042∗∗
1.065
1.011
1.081∗∗,++
Predicted response to a 1 standard deviation increase in the percentage of free lunch students
in the school
Regular teacher
Regular teacher plus 2 qualifications
1.043∗∗
1.026
1.002
0.983
1.099∗∗
1.022
1.071∗∗
1.091
Predicted response to a 10 percentage point increase in percentage of nonwhite students in the district
0.968∗∗
0.869∗∗,++
Regular teacher plus 2 qualifications
1.029∗∗
1.070∗∗
1.008
0.996
1.018
1.037
Regular teacher
Notes: ++ and + denote whether the underlying hazard coefficient for a teacher with strong qualifi-
cations differs from the underlying hazard coefficient for a teacher with regular qualifications at the
.05 level and .10 levels, respectively.
∗statistically significant at the .10 level; ∗∗statistically significant at the .05 level.
increase in the school’s free lunch percentage increases it by about 3 percent.
Because the models separately control for student demographics at the district
level, the simulated changes in school demographics should be interpreted as
responses to changes in one school’s characteristics relative to those of other
schools. With the exception of a change in the school’s free lunch percentage,
which increases the probability that the teacher will switch to another school
within the same district, the other demographic changes highlighted in the
424
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
f
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
Table 8. Salary Differentials (as a Percent of Salary) Required to Offset the
Fraction Nonwhite at the School Level on the Overall Departure Hazard
Difference in Nonwhite Share (Percentage Points)
Regular teacher
Strong teacher
10
1.5
10.2
20
3.0
23.1
30
4.5
34.7
40
6.3
46.3
50
7.5
58.3
table for a regular teacher all affect the odds that the teacher leaves the district
or the profession, and not the odds of moving to another school within the
district. For teachers with strong qualifications, the general patterns of hazard
ratios are similar to those for regular teachers. Importantly, however, those
with strong qualifications exhibit a much more muted response to salary
differentials (0.944 hazard ratio vs. 0.861) and a more pronounced response
to the nonwhite share of students (1.069 hazard ratio vs. 1.023).
These patterns indicate that salary differentials are a relatively powerful
motivator for keeping regular teachers in their initial teaching spells in their
original schools but a far less powerful motivator for teachers with strong
qualifications. In particular, table 8 shows the simulated salary increases that
would be required to counter the effects of differing percentages of nonwhite
students in a particular school for the two types of teachers. For a regular
teacher, the table indicates that a small salary increase of 3 percent would
suffice to offset a 20 percentage point difference in the nonwhite share of
students in the teacher’s current school, and a 7.5 percent salary increase
would offset a 50 percentage point difference. We note that these estimates,
which under plausible assumptions once again are upper bounds, represent
salary differentials that are within the range of observed salary differences in
our data and are also within the realm of political feasibility.
To retain teachers with strong qualifications in schools with high nonwhite
shares, in contrast, the required salary increases are far higher, ranging from
over 10 percent to offset a small percentage point difference in the nonwhite
share to 58.3 percent to offset a 50 percentage point difference. We note that
these projected salary differentials are large relative to the observed variation
in actual salaries in our data and hence represent out-of-sample predictions.
While that means we cannot be very confident about the precise numbers, we
can conclude that the salary differences required to retain teachers with strong
qualifications are high and likely beyond the realm of political feasibility.27
27. This statement is true even with the additional qualification that the coefficients on the salary
estimates may be biased downward, which would lead to an overstatement of the required salary
differentials.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
f
/
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
f
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
425
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
Consistent with this finding, salary also emerges as a relatively ineffective
policy tool for changing the behavior of the more experienced teachers in
later teaching spells. That conclusion emerges from panel B of table 7, which
shows that salary differentials have little or no effect on the exit decisions of
such teachers.28 In particular, the entries in the top line indicate that a 10
percent increase in district salary could possibly even induce an increase in
the hazard of exiting, although the coefficient is only marginally significant.
Further, such a salary increase would have essentially no effect on the hazard
ratio for teachers with strong qualifications.
At the same time, however, these experienced teachers respond just as
strongly to the shares of nonwhite students or low-income students in their
schools as do the teachers in initial spells, with teachers having strong qualifi-
cations being more responsive than those with regular qualifications. Because
they tend to be established in a community, they are more likely than inexpe-
rienced teachers to respond to high percentages of nonwhite students in their
current school by transferring to another school within the same district rather
than moving to another district or dropping out of teaching. With respect to
district-level differences in the share of nonwhite students in the district, both
regular and strong teachers exhibit higher probabilities of leaving the profes-
sion. We have not replicated table 8 for teachers in these later teaching spells
since the lack of responsiveness of such teachers to salary differentials rules
out salary differentials as a tool for offsetting the demographic characteristics
of the schools.
Responses to Other Labor Market Conditions, Including Local Bonus Programs
Tables 4 and 5 also provide results related to other labor market conditions.
First, the coefficients on teacher salaries in surrounding districts indicate
the expected finding that, controlling for the salary in her current district, a
teacher is more likely to switch districts the higher the teacher salaries are
elsewhere. Second, but somewhat harder to explain, is that a teacher is also
more likely to change districts but not to leave the profession in response to
higher nonteaching salaries in the local area. Given that we have also controlled
for the local unemployment rate, however, those higher salaries in nonteaching
jobs need not be associated with job openings. As expected, teachers respond
to higher local unemployment rates by reducing the rate at which they leave
the profession in the current year.
28. Based on a different model specification and with data from Texas, Hanushek, Kain, and Rivkin
(2004) conclude that the power of salary differentials reaches a peak for teachers with 3–5 years of
experience but falls off for more experienced teachers. Their findings seem roughly consistent with
ours but are hard to compare, given that we focus on teaching spells, not years of experience.
426
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
/
f
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
Some positive, but at best limited, evidence emerges related to the Equity
Plus programs in Charlotte-Mecklenburg and Winston-Salem. Recall that the
relevant coefficients are those associated with designation as an Equity Plus
program in the current year, controlling for whether a school ever met the
criteria for the program. Consistent with the goals of these programs, three
out of four of the relevant hazard ratios in the first column for teachers in
either initial or subsequent spells are less than one. Although these coefficients
suggest that the program was associated with a lower overall departure hazard,
only one of them (for initial spells in Winston-Salem) is even marginally
significant. The most significant of all the relevant coefficients related to the
two programs is the 0.648 coefficient for the probability that a teacher in an
initial teaching spell in Charlotte-Mecklenburg changes districts. It is a bit
puzzling why the program in that city would reduce the odds that a teacher
would leave the district but not the odds that she would leave the designated
school in which she received the bonus.
The Statewide Bonus Program
Because of the complicated eligibility conditions surrounding the state’s short-
lived $1,800 bonus program, we augmented the basic models of the form shown in tables 4 and 5 with a set of six additional variables and limited the analysis to middle and high schools. Although the specifications are similar in spirit to those we present in Clotfelter et al. 2008, they differ in that these models are estimated separately for teachers in their initial or subsequent teaching spells, they differentiate exit routes, and they include only the teachers starting teaching spells during the relevant period. Of most interest are the coefficients of the variable indicating that a teacher was eligible to receive a $1,800 bonus.29 The other coefficients refer to whether the teacher was
eligible for the bonus (defined as a certified teacher of math, science, or special
education) in an eligible school (defined as a high-poverty middle school or a
low-performing high school), both directly and interacted with the years the
program was in existence.
Table 9 reports results for all teachers in their initial spells (panel A) and for
all teachers in subsequent spells (panel B). No distinction is made in this table
between teachers with regular or strong qualifications.30 The most compelling
findings emerge in panel B. The relevant coefficients imply that, consistent
29. We used an indicator variable rather than adding the bonus amount to a teacher’s salary because
of the temporary nature of the bonus, which differentiates it from a permanent increase in salary
(Clotfelter et al. 2008). The coefficient of the indicator represents a difference-in-difference estimate
of the effect of receiving the bonus.
30. Models that interact all the bonus variables with a measure of strong preservice qualifications
provide some hints that the effects may be more pronounced for regular than for strong teachers,
but the differences are not statistically significant.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
/
f
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
427
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
Table 9. Effects of the $1,800 Bonus Program Panel A: Initial Teaching Spells Received $1,800 bonus
Eligible teacher
Eligible school
Eligible teacher 2002–4
Eligible school 2002–4
Eligible teacher∗Eligible school
All Exit
Routes
Leave
Teaching
Exit Route
Switch
Districts
1.065
0.969
0.978
0.991
1.018
0.992
0.943
0.979
0.985
0.807∗∗∗
1.063
0.981
0.921
1.007
0.891∗
1.102
0.937
1.135
Change
Schools
1.460∗∗
0.890∗∗∗
1.013
1.328∗∗∗
1.002
0.962
Number of teacher-years
61,713
61,713
61,713
61,713
Panel B: Subsequent Teaching Spells
Received $1,800 bonus
Eligible teacher
Eligible school
Eligible teacher 2002–4
Eligible school 2002–4
Eligible teacher∗Eligible school
0.860∗
1.083∗∗∗
0.719∗∗
1.210∗∗∗
0.970
0.996
1.061
1.024
1.013
0.941
1.028
1.000
0.979
1.035
0.880∗
1.141
1.139
0.956
1.022
0.898∗∗
0.951
1.052
1.074
1.113
Number of teacher-years
50,904
50,904
50,904
50,904
∗statistically significant at the .10 level; ∗∗statistically significant at the .05 level; ∗∗∗statistically
significant at the .01 level.
with the goals of the program, experienced teachers who received the bonus
were 14 percent less likely to leave their school in the following year than were
other teachers, all other factors held constant. In addition, they were 28 percent
less likely to leave the profession. In contrast, the program did not have its
intended effect on teachers in their first teaching spells and, in fact, appears to
have increased the probability that they would move to another school within
the district. These patterns are generally consistent with those from our earlier
study, where we found that the statewide bonus program had a larger effect
on experienced than on inexperienced teachers (Clotfelter, Ladd, and Vigdor
2008).
At the same time, the greater responsiveness to the bonus among the more
experienced teachers may at first appear inconsistent with the results reported
in table 8 showing larger responsiveness to salary differentials among teachers
in their first spells. The two findings can be reconciled by the recognition that
many teachers expected the bonus program to be short lived, which in fact
it turned out to be. It is quite plausible that teachers in their first teaching
spells would be far more responsive to permanent salary differentials than
428
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
f
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
f
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
to short-term bonuses in making decisions about whether to remain in their
current position. More experienced teachers, in contrast, may well perceive
the bonus as a short-term incentive to remain in teaching or in their current
school slightly longer than they otherwise would have.
6. CONCLUSION
Among the possible policies for ensuring equal access of racial and socioe-
conomic groups of students to quality educational resources at the school
level, two are of particular interest. One is to distribute students of all groups
evenly across schools, in which case the pattern by which resources (such
as teachers with strong qualifications) are distributed across schools would
have no adverse equity consequences. The racial desegregation that federal
courts pushed in the 1960s and 1970s could be interpreted as a version of
this first policy strategy. This approach has always been problematic, however,
because existing patterns of residential segregation across states, counties, or
other geographic regions make it difficult, if not impossible, to attain an even
distribution of students across schools within districts, let alone metropolitan
areas or states. Moreover, recent court decisions have all but precluded the
possibility of using this strategy to promote educational equity within school
districts.
A second method of promoting equity in the presence of school segrega-
tion is to use policy levers to equalize resources across schools. Research has
consistently shown that the most significant educational resource—teacher
quality—is distributed very unevenly among schools to the clear disadvantage
of minority students and those from low-income families. The results of this
study highlight the difficulties inherent in overcoming this historical pattern
using the most obvious available financial policy lever—differential teacher
salaries.
On the positive side, our analysis indicates that salary differentials do
have some role to play in easing the challenge that hard-to-staff schools face in
attracting teachers with strong qualifications. The more schools are segregated
(particularly by race), the greater the required salary differentials needed to
level the playing field. In addition, our results indicate that salary differentials
of feasible magnitudes can counter the repelling effects of concentrations of
disadvantaged students for at least one group of teachers—those with average
qualifications who are in their first teaching spell.
On the negative side, salary differentials emerge as a far less effective tool
for changing the school departure behavior of teachers with strong preservice
qualifications or those who are no longer in their first teaching spells. This
conclusion reflects our findings that such teachers are both more responsive
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
/
f
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
429
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
to the racial and socioeconomic mix of a school’s students and less responsive
to salary than are their less well qualified counterparts when making decisions
about remaining in their current school, moving to another school or district,
or leaving the teaching profession. Thus, as we reported in table 8, for teach-
ers with strong preservice qualifications in their initial teaching spells, the
simulated salary differentials required to neutralize the effect of large concen-
trations of disadvantaged students are large and on the order of 40–50 percent
of salary. In addition, taken literally, our estimates for teachers in subsequent
spells imply that no salary differentials would be large enough to compensate
them for being in schools with concentrations of disadvantaged students.
Given these findings, we are not optimistic about the power of salary
differentials alone to promote educational equity in the context of schools
that are highly segregated by educational disadvantage, and particularly by
race. Although such differentials, whether in the form of permanent salary
differences or short-run bonus programs, may reduce turnover in hard-to-
staff schools, which in itself is a desirable outcome, and may keep some
teachers from leaving the profession, they are far less effective in equalizing
the quality of teachers across schools. Thus even with a judicious use of salary
differentials specifically designed to promote a more equitable distribution of
teachers across schools, the more segregated the schools are, the more unequal
is likely to be the quality of teachers across schools.
This research was supported by a grant from the U.S. Department of Education through
the Center for the Analysis of Longitudinal Data (CALDER) in Washington, DC. Re-
search support was also provided by the Russell Sage Foundation and the Spencer
Foundation. The authors are grateful to the North Carolina Education Research Data
Center for making the data available and to research assistants Janeil Belle, Reid
Chisholm, Sarah Gordon, Robert Malme, Patten Priestley, Valorie Rawlston, Shirley
Richards, and Russ Triplett.
REFERENCES
Baugh, William H., and Joe A. Stone. 1982. Mobility and wage equilibration in the
education labor market. Economics of Education Review 2(3): 253–74.
Becker, Howard. 1952. The career of the Chicago public school teacher. American
Journal of Sociology 57: 470–77.
Betts, Julian R., Kim S. Rueben, and Anne Danenberg. 2000. Equal resources, equal
outcomes? The distribution of school resources and student achievement in California. San
Francisco: Public Policy Institute of California.
Boyd, Donald, Pam Grossman, Hamilton Lankford, Susanna Loeb, and James Wyckoff.
2008. Who leaves? Teacher attrition and student achievement. NBER Working Paper
No. 14022.
430
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
f
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
Boyd, Donald, Hamilton Lankford, Susanna Loeb, and James Wyckoff. 2005. Explain-
ing the short careers of high-achieving teachers in schools with low-performing stu-
dents. American Economic Review 95: 166–71.
Clotfelter, Charles T., Elizabeth Glennie, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor.
2008. Would higher salaries keep teachers in high-poverty schools? Evidence from
a policy intervention in North Carolina. Journal of Public Economics 92: 1352–
70.
Clotfelter, Charles T., Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor. 2003. Segregation and
resegregation in North Carolina’s public school classrooms. North Carolina Law Review
81: 1463–1511.
Clotfelter, Charles T., Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor. 2005. Who teaches whom?
Race and the distribution of novice teachers. Economics of Education Review 24(4):
377–92.
Clotfelter, Charles T., Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor. 2006. Teacher-student
matching and the assessment of teacher effectiveness. Journal of Human Resources
41(4): 778–820.
Clotfelter, Charles T., Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor. 2007. Teacher credentials
and student achievement: Longitudinal analysis with student fixed effects. Economics
of Education Review 26(6): 673–82.
Clotfelter, Charles T., Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor. 2008. School segregation
under color-blind jurisprudence: The case of North Carolina. Virginia Journal of Social
Policy and the Law 16: 46–86.
Clotfelter, Charles T., Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor. 2010. Teacher credentials
and student achievement in high school: A cross-subject analysis with fixed effects.
Journal of Human Resources 45(3): 655–81.
Clotfelter, Charles T., Helen F. Ladd, Jacob L. Vigdor, and Roger A. Diaz. 2004. Do
school accountability systems make it more difficult for low-performing schools to
attract and retain high-quality teachers? Journal of Policy Analysis and Management
23(2): 251–71.
Clotfelter, Charles T., Helen F. Ladd, Jacob L. Vigdor, and Justin Wheeler. 2007. High
poverty schools and the distribution of teachers and principals. North Carolina Law
Review 85(5): 1345–79.
Dolton, Peter, and Wilbert van der Klaauw. 1995. Leaving teaching in the UK: A duration
analysis. Economic Journal 105: 431–44.
Falch, Torberg, and Bjarne Strom. 2005. Teacher turnover and non-pecuniary factors.
Economics of Education Review 24(6): 611–31.
Feng, Li, and Tim R. Sass. 2008. Teacher quality and teacher mobility. Unpublished
paper, SUNY Fredonia.
Gleason, Philip M. 1995. Participation in the national school lunch program and
the school breakfast program. American Journal of Clinical Nutrition 61(1): 213S–
20S.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
f
/
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
f
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
431
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
Goldhaber, Dan. 2008. Teachers matter, but effective teacher quality policies are elu-
sive. In Handbook of research in education finance and policy, edited by Helen F. Ladd
and Edward B. Fiske, pp. 146–65. New York: Routledge.
Goldhaber, Dan, and Emily Anthony. 2007. Can teacher quality be effectively assessed?
National Board certification as a signal of effective teaching. Review of Economics and
Statistics 89(1): 134–50.
Goldhaber, Dan, Bethany Gross, and Daniel Player. 2009. Teacher career paths, teacher
quality, and persistence in the classroom: Are schools keeping their best? CALDER
Working Paper No. 29.
Greenberg, David, and John McCall. 1974. Teacher mobility and allocation. Journal of
Human Resources 9(4): 480–502.
Gritz, R. Mark, and Neil D. Theobald. 1996. The effects of school district spend-
ing priorities on length of stay in teaching. Journal of Human Resources 31(3): 477–
512.
Hanushek, Eric, John Kain, Daniel O’Brien, and Steven Rivkin. 2005. The market for
teacher quality. NBER Working Paper No. 11154.
Hanushek, Eric, John Kain, and Steven Rivkin. 2004. Why public schools lose teachers.
Journal of Human Resources 39(2): 326–54.
Hollingshead, August B. 1949. Elmtown’s youth: The impact of social classes on adolescents.
New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Imazeki, Jennifer. 2005. Teacher salaries and teacher attrition. Economics of Education
Review 24: 431–49.
Jackson, C. Kirabo. 2009. Student demographics, teacher sorting and teacher quality:
Evidence from the end of school desegregation. Journal of Labor Economics 27(2): 213–
56.
Johnson, Susan Moore, and Sarah E. Birkeland. 2003. Pursuing a “sense of success”:
New teachers explain their career decisions. American Educational Research Journal
40(3): 581–617.
Koedel, Cory, and Julian R. Betts. 2007. Re-examining the role of teacher quality in the
educational production function. Working Paper No. 708, University of Missouri.
Krieg, John M. 2006. Teacher quality and attrition. Economics of Education Review 25(1):
13–27.
Ladd, Helen F. Forthcoming. Teacher working conditions: How predictive of policy
relevant outcomes? Education Evaluation and Policy Analysis. In press.
Ladd, Helen F. 2008. Reflections on equity, adequacy, and weighted student funding.
Education Finance and Policy 3(4): 402–23.
Lankford, Hamilton, Susanna Loeb, and James Wyckoff. 2002. Teacher sorting and
the plight of urban schools: A descriptive analysis. Educational Evaluation and Policy
Analysis 24: 37–62.
432
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
f
/
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
Lockwood, J. R., Daniel F. McCaffrey, and Tim R. Sass. 2008. The intertemporal
stability of teacher effect estimates. Paper prepared for the National Conference on
Value-Added Modeling, University of Wisconsin, Madison, April.
Milanowski, Anthony T., Hope Longwell-Grice, Felicia Saffold, Janice Jones, Kirsten
Schomisch, and Allan Odden. 2009. Recruiting new teachers to urban school districts:
What incentives will work? International Journal of Education Policy and Leadership 4(8):
1–13.
Mont, Daniel, and Daniel I. Rees. 1996. The influence of classroom characteristics on
high school teacher turnover. Economic Inquiry 34: 152–67.
Murnane, Richard J., and Randall J. Olsen. 1989. Will there be enough teachers?
American Economic Review 79: 242–46.
Murnane, Richard J., and Randall J. Olsen. 1990. The effects of salaries and opportunity
costs on length of stay in teaching: Evidence from North Carolina. Journal of Human
Resources 25(1): 106–24.
Podgursky, Michael, Ryan Monroe, and Donald Watson. 2004. The academic quality
of public school teachers: An analysis of entry and exit behavior. Economics of Education
Review 23: 507–18.
Reed, Deborah, Kim S. Rueben, and Elisa Barbour. 2006. Retention of new teachers in
California. San Francisco: Public Policy Institute of California.
Rickman, Bill D., and Carl D. Parker. 1990. Alternative wages and teacher mobility: A
human capital approach. Economics of Education Review 9(2): 127–36.
Roemer, John E. 1998. Equality of opportunity. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Scafidi, Benjamin, David Sjoquist, and Todd R. Stinebrickner. 2007. Race, poverty, and
teacher mobility. Economics of Education Review 26(2): 145–59.
Stinebrickner, Todd R. 1998. An empirical investigation of teacher attrition. Economics
of Education Review 17(2): 127–36.
Walden, Michael L., and Zulai Sogutlu. 2001. Determinants of intrastate variation in
teacher salaries. Economics of Education Review 20(1): 63–70.
APPENDIX
DATA DEFINITIONS
Local Teacher Salary Supplements
Teacher salaries in North Carolina are the sum of (1) a mandated state portion
taken from an annually revised schedule based on degree and years of expe-
rience and (2) an optional local supplement added by most school districts.
Some districts offer a flat rate supplement for all teachers; others offer a uni-
form percentage increase in the state salary; and some make the supplement
a function of such things as certification status, years of experience, or degree
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
f
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
433
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
level. Since these formulas are not stored centrally, the information available
to calculate them is generally not available for any but the most recent years
covered by our data set. The only information on local supplements that is
available over all years in our data set is the total amount of supplements paid
by a district for a school year.
Since the form of the local supplement necessarily affects the salary sched-
ule facing teachers in various districts, we sought to retain the differences in
formulas. We therefore combined the aggregate amount paid in each district
with information on the form of the supplement for the 2004–5 year, on
the assumption that the form of the supplement did not change over time.
Thus for districts whose local supplement was a flat amount in 2004–5, we
assumed that their local supplements were flat amounts in other years. For
these districts, therefore, we calculated each teacher’s local supplement to be
the average supplement paid to teachers in that district in the correspond-
ing year. For districts whose supplements were simple percentages of the
state-determined salary, we determined the rate as the ratio of the total local
supplement for teachers to the total state salary bill for teachers in the district
in that year.
For the districts that applied exact percentage rates to different classes of
teachers, we computed the percentage rates that would yield a total district
supplement equal to the reported total. For these districts, we first applied
the 2004–5 rates by category (most of these districts differentiated by expe-
rience categories), calculated the implied total amount, noted the percentage
error, then adjusted the rates for all categories proportionately so that the
adjusted percentages yielded the correct district total. For a number of dis-
tricts we were able to obtain the formulas used in 2001–2 and were able
to compare the categories and percentage rates to those for 2004–5. If the
earlier formulas differed, we used the 2001–2 formulas as the basis for the
estimates for 2001–2 and earlier years, using the same approach described
above.
For the remaining districts, whose local supplement was determined by
more involved formulas, we compared the supplements given in tabular form
to the pattern of salaries given in the state’s salary tables to determine if the
formula was closer to a flat amount or to a fixed proportion. Specifically, two
parameters were calculated for the supplements given in tabular form: average
experience progression (the average increase per year of experience calculated
as an exponential growth rate) and the salary premium given to teachers with
a master’s degree as compared to those with a bachelor’s. In the state’s salary
scale for 2004–5, average experience progression was 0.020, and the master’s
degree premium for teachers with ten years of experience was 10.0 percent.
For districts that expressed their supplement in tabular format, the average
434
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
f
/
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
f
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
experience progression was calculated by comparing supplements for bach-
elor’s level teachers at three and twenty-nine years, and the master’s degree
premium, if any, was calculated at ten years of experience. A district was as-
sumed to have a proportionate form for its supplement if either one of these
rates exceeded the state rate or if both were more than half the state rate for that
year. Otherwise, a district’s supplement was assumed to be a flat amount for all
teachers. Proportional formulas could be of four types: (1) a simple percentage
of the state salary, (2) a percentage of the state salary based on the teacher’s de-
gree, (3) a percentage based on the teacher’s experience (number of years teach-
ing), and (4) a percentage that used both degree and experience. The breakdown
of each type for the 117 districts in 2003–4 was (1) 73, (2) 2, (3) 8, and (4) 2; the
remaining districts had either an additive supplement (22) or no supplement at
all (10).
Arriving at a formula for each district that both retained the form that was
used in 2004–5 and was consistent with the aggregate value of supplements
paid in the district in a given year required a two-step estimation procedure. In
the first step, the applicable formula for each district was used to calculate the
supplement amount for each teacher in each district. In the second step, the
formulas used in the first step were adjusted so that the total of all supplements
calculated for each district would be equal to the total for the district given in
the supplement data.
Alternative Teacher Salaries
To assess a teacher’s earnings alternatives, we sought to calculate the aver-
age teacher salary available in nearby school districts. To keep to a reasonable
level the amount of necessary calculations, we compared for one of six stan-
dard teacher profiles the salary available in a teacher’s own district with the
enrollment-weighted average salary available in districts within a thirty-mile
radius (measured between centroids) of the teacher’s own district. These six
profiles combined two certificate types (bachelor’s and master’s) and three
experience categories: 0–4 years of experience (median 2); 5–11 years (median
8), and 12 or more years (median assumed to be 18). The measure of relative
teaching salaries is the logarithm of the ratio of the own-district teacher salary
to the average regional teacher salary, both defined for the category into which
each teacher falls.
To illustrate the importance of the functional form used in calculating
local supplements, the salary ratio of Wake to neighboring Franklin County in
2003–4 ranged from 1.07 for inexperienced teachers with a bachelor’s degree
to 1.12 for teachers holding a master’s having twelve or more years teaching
experience.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
f
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
f
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
435
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
Nonteaching Salaries
The measure of nonteaching salaries is the employment-weighted average
of salaries in all counties within a thirty-mile radius of the (centroid of the)
school district of the teacher in question. The definition of nonteaching earn-
ings we use is private employment (equal to total employment minus farm
employment and government employment), a definition that includes pro-
prietors (from BEA Regional Economic Accounts Regional Economic Infor-
mation System data 1995–2003; available www.bea.gov/regional/reis, Table
CA-6, Compensation by Industry, and CA-25, Total Employment by Industry).
An alternative definition, nonfarm wage and salary employment (nonfarm em-
ployment minus nonfarm proprietor employment), a definition that includes
government, yielded similar results.
Classification of Schools by Level
In North Carolina, the most common grade ranges corresponding to each of
the three school levels are elementary (K−5 or PK−5), middle school (6–8),
and high school (9–12). In 1999–2000, over 70 percent of the state’s public
schools conformed to one of these grade ranges. To classify the remaining
schools, each was assigned to the level in which most of its grades fell, or to
the lower level in the case of equal numbers in two levels. Thus, for example,
schools covering grades 3–5 are classified as elementary and those with 6–12
are classified as high schools.
College Selectivity
The categories were derived from information from Barron’s College Admis-
sions Selector for 1988, based on information for first-year students in each
university in 1986–87. Our category “very competitive” includes universities
rated as most competitive, highly competitive, or very competitive; “compet-
itive” includes those rated as competitive; “less competitive” includes those
rated as less competitive or noncompetitive; and “unranked” includes spe-
cial programs such as art schools, international universities, or universities
for which we were not able to find a rating. Barron’s uses criteria such as
the median entrance examination scores, percentages of students scoring five
hundred and above and six hundred and above on both the math and verbal
parts of the SAT or comparable scores for the ACT, the percentage of students
who ranked in the upper fifth or two-fifths of their high school class, and the
percentage of applicants who were accepted. If information for a university
was missing for 1988, we substituted the ranking for the 1979 or 1999 selector,
with the choice varying with the era in which the teacher attended college.
436
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
f
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
f
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Charles T. Clotfelter, Helen F. Ladd, and Jacob L. Vigdor
Teacher Test Scores
Teachers took a variety of standardized tests as part of the state’s licensure
requirements. We used results from nineteen of the most frequently taken
tests. We formed a standardized licensure test score variable for each teacher
by converting test scores from different test administrations in North Carolina
to standardized scores using the means and standard deviations for tests taken
in each year by all teachers in our data set. We normalized test scores on each of
these tests separately for each year the test was administered based on means
and standard deviations from test scores for all teachers in our data set and
then assigned to each teacher the average standardized score on the tests taken
by that teacher.
Classification of Districts
All districts in counties that were 45 percent or more urban in 1990 were
classified as urban, as were all city districts in any county with enrollments of
at least two thousand in 2001–2, not counting charter school enrollments. The
boundaries between coastal, Piedmont, and mountain counties were taken
from North Carolina Division of Travel and Tourism, Yours to Discover: North
Carolina State Parks and Recreation Areas (1998). For the classification of spe-
cific districts, see Clotfelter, Ladd, and Vigdor (2003, Appendix A).
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
f
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
f
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
437
TEACHER MOBILITY, SEGREGATION, AND PAY
Table A.1. Descriptive Statistics for the Probit Sample
Mean
SD
Min
Max
School Characteristics
Middle
High school
Nonwhite, K–12 (%)
Building age
Free lunch, elementary (%)∗
Free lunch, middle (%)∗
Free lunch, high school (%)∗
District Characteristics
Free lunch (%)
Nonwhite (%)
Enrollment (ln)
Growth
Rural
Coastal
Mountain
Beach
Salary (BA + 2) (ln)
Labor Market Characteristics
Alt. salary (ln)
Unemployment rate
Years
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
0.24
0.28
43.36
35.53
40.66
33.22
20.25
30.56
40.81
10.00
0.02
0.37
0.16
0.17
0.05
10.16
10.39
4.78
0.12
0.11
0.12
0.13
0.12
0.12
0.12
0.04
0.43
0.45
25.82
18.48
21.42
18.47
15.40
11.81
18.57
1.08
0.01
0.48
0.36
0.38
0.23
0.08
0.64
2.05
0.33
0.32
0.33
0.33
0.33
0.33
0.32
0.20
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0.82
6.50
−0.03
0
0
0
0
9.97
0
1.20
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
1
100.00
93.00
99.14
94.87
95.00
75.87
97.42
11.66
0.06
1
1
1
1
10.31
10.63
18.20
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
N = 129,388
∗Calculated separately by school level.
438
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
f
/
e
d
u
e
d
p
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
/
6
3
3
9
9
1
6
8
9
2
7
9
e
d
p
_
a
_
0
0
0
4
0
p
d
.
f
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3