Presidential Essay
James W. 格思里
Department of
领导, 政策
and Organization
Peabody College of
Vanderbilt
大学
230 Appleton Place
Nashville, TN
37203-5721
电子邮件:
jwgxiii@sbcglobal.net
“MODERN” EDUCATION FINANCE:
HOW IT DIFFERS FROM THE
“OLD” AND THE ANALYTIC AND
DATA COLLECTION CHANGES IT
IMPLIES
抽象的
This article contends that a new concept of education
finance has emerged in response to substantial alter-
ations in the U.S. education policy environment. 这
major distinction between modern and old is that the
latter was principally concerned with arrangements of
inputs in K–12 schooling. The former, modern-era edu-
cation finance, is concerned with relationships of inputs
to schooling outcomes. This modern education finance
paradigm provokes a need for (1) research and data
extending into the operations of education itself, 不是
just financing; (2) far more fine-grained information
than now exists regarding education inputs, 通过-
看跌期权, and outputs; (3) cohesive concepts for linking
these data elements with one another to better under-
stand their interactions; (4) an expanded set of outcome
措施; (5) information about how previously public
sector, dominant-education offerings interact with ex-
panded private market conditions; 和 (6) better linkage
between K–12 and postsecondary data and analyses.
C(西德:1) 2006 American Education Finance Association
3
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
F
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
F
.
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
“MODERN” EDUCATION FINANCE
介绍
By what means can student academic performance be elevated and what will
it cost to accomplish this purpose? How can achievement gaps between lower-
and higher-income students be narrowed, and what education finance and
education data collection implications accompany this objective? Which in-
structional techniques are most cost effective? To what extent can market
军队, competition, pay-for-performance incentives, and enhanced provision
of schooling elevate student performance and client satisfaction? What com-
binations of individual training and incentives are most likely to lead to higher
teacher productivity? Can elementary and secondary education be better in-
tegrated with postsecondary schooling, and do financing arrangements offer
solutions for linking these disparate systems?
These questions illustrate the evolving education policy climate and emerg-
ing challenges contained in modern K–12 education finance. Scholarly issues
and analytic techniques related to contemporary policy challenges are substan-
tially different from those dominating America’s education finance research
agendas even two decades ago. The post–World War II concern of most educa-
tion finance specialists had been directed toward problems of resource input,
particularly issues of resource equality. Until the late 1980s, this conceptual
shift in education finance, to issues of resource sufficiency and efficiency and
the consequences of market competition, exhibited an evolutionary trajectory.
然而, during the late twentieth century, intensified public expectations
for elementary and secondary education achievement, judicial interventions
in state school financing, new state school aid programs addressing issues of
“adequacy,” the federally enacted No Child Left Behind Act (NCLB), an emer-
gence of a more rigorous scientific paradigm in education research generally,
and evolution of strategies for effective school operation have accelerated the
rate at which modern is superseding old in education finance. Albeit not
quite an abrupt revolution, this transformation has occurred with remarkable
速度.
MODERN EDUCATION FINANCE: WHAT IS NEW AND HOW THE NEW
DIFFERS FROM THE OLD
There is no clear chronological separation between modern and old where edu-
cation finance is concerned. Much that can be characterized as old persists and
is unlikely to disappear anytime soon. 例如, early-twentieth-century
funding mechanisms and pupil weighting procedures developed by George
D. Strayer, Robert M. Haig, and Paul R. Mort are near mirror images within
today’s current performance policy paradigm. 反过来, what can be claimed
to be modern has existed in nascent form for a long time. Charles S. Benson’s
4
EDUCATION FINANCE AND POLICY
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
/
F
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
F
.
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
James W. 格思里
桌子 1 Summary Comparison of “Old” and “Modern” Education Finance
Issue/Dimension
“Old” Education Finance
Value orientation
equity (distributional and
Decision dynamic
taxpayer)
政治的
Distribution objective
per pupil parity
Relative concern for pupil
最小的
“performance”
Equity concern for tax sources
高的
and mechanisms
Linkage to instructional
Minimal
成分
Reliance upon evidentiary
最小的
“Modern” Education
Finance
efficiency/productivity
(accountability)
rational and political
per pupil sufficiency and
performance motivation
高的
reduced
desired
desired
基础
Policy system oversight
School district incentive
scrutiny of overall revenue
amount and distributional
equity
scrutiny of overall revenue
金额, distributional
equity, and outcomes
maximize income via input
manipulation (enrollment
census and student
分类)
maximize income via input
manipulation and outcome
maximization
student, classroom, 学校,
区, 状态, and nation
Data orientation
state and local districts
Analytic orientation
resource comparisons
resource and performance
相互作用
The Cheerful Prospect: A Statement of the Future of American Education (1965)
proposed integrating vocational and academic track education in an effort to
eliminate educational disparity and improve efficiency. Though his writing did
not initially leverage reform, it was acknowledged as pivotal in the federal en-
actment of the Carl D. Perkins Vocational and Applied Technology Education
Act (1990) and School-to-Work Opportunities Act (1994).
This section presents a brief snapshot of significant conditions that fostered
modern K-12 finance’s emergence into policy’s prime time. 桌子 1 提供
a summary characterizing modern and old education finance across eleven
comparison dimensions to which this article later returns.
The release of A Nation at Risk (NCEE 1983) triggered a sustained period of
public concern for and policy-maker attention to higher levels of performance
for public schools in the United States. 例如, Bill Honig’s election in
1984 as California’s highly visible Superintendent of Public Instruction sent an
electoral signal regarding significance of this policy shift. During his campaign
Honig claimed that his incumbent opponent had concentrated on access and
equity at the price of excellence and higher pupil performance. Honig stayed
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
F
/
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
.
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
5
“MODERN” EDUCATION FINANCE
true to his campaign promises upon election to office and advocated enactment
of elevated pupil performance standards.
Five years thereafter, a highly publicized 1989 summit conference of Amer-
ica’s governors in Charlottesville, 弗吉尼亚州, organized by President George
H. 瓦. 衬套, resulted in a host of new national and state-level policies. 为了
例子, a set of six national goals for educational improvement, later ex-
panded to eight goals during the Clinton administration, were incorporated
into legislation by Congress, while heightened performance expectations for
学生, accompanying accountability provisions for schools and districts,
and state student achievement testing programs proliferated at the state
等级.
Post–A Nation at Risk reforms were generally of two kinds. One was height-
ened expectations including intensified high school requirements, reduction
of high school electives, and more stringent college admission standards. 这
was an era of student motivation efforts such as “No Pass, No Play” and “No
Graduate, No Drive” state statutes (Webb, Covington, and Guthrie 1993). 在
添加, more money flowed to elevate teacher salaries.
The aftermath of the 1989 Charlottesville summit marked a second “post-
A Nation At Risk” education reform phase. Initial efforts at heightened rigor
and spending had resulted in only minimal achievement gains, as indicated
by trends in average National Assessment of Educational Progress (NAEP)
scores for the nation in reading, mathematics, and science (坎贝尔, Hombo,
and Mazzeo 2000). Emergence of systemic reform, sometimes referred to as
standards-based reform, outlined in a seminal article by Smith and O’Day
(1991), signaled a second phase. Smith and O’Day’s ideas further propelled
policy proposals for aligning components of the educational system, linking
标准, statewide standardized student achievement tests, teacher licens-
ing requirements, instructional materials, professional development, 状态
capacity-building subsidies, performance ratings and school report cards,
and positive and negative sanctions for achievement progress. These initia-
tives not only became the hallmark of the Clinton administration’s educa-
tional policies (Vinovski 1996) but also facilitated a new understanding that
school revenue generation and distribution arrangements were something of
an operating precondition, separated from the purposes of schooling under
the old education finance paradigm. The emerging understanding empha-
sized the need to forge a link between these revenue matters and schooling
结果.
Enactment of NCLB in 2001 solidified concern for schooling outcomes,
rather than the prior era’s assumed quality criterion of resource inputs. NCLB
poignantly signifies the outcome-oriented production model underpinning
modern education finance.
6
EDUCATION FINANCE AND POLICY
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
F
/
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
.
F
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
James W. 格思里
Judicial action has also dramatically contributed to the emergence of
“modern” education finance. Following Rose v. Council for Better Education
(1989) in Kentucky, 例如, judicial decisions such as Campbell in
Wyoming (1995), Campaign for Fiscal Equity v. 状态 (2003) in New York,
Lakeview School District v. Huckabee (2001) in Arkansas, and West Orange-Cove
v. 纳尔逊 (2001) in Texas have reinforced government’s obligation to provide
revenues sufficient to ensure that students have an opportunity to achieve ele-
vated standards. The entire revenue sufficiency movement, made possible by
the advent of state-promulgated curriculum standards or learning standards,
has virtually replaced old-style, dollar-for-dollar parity concerns as an equity
basis for judicial intervention. 这 1999 National Research Council Report,
“Making Money Matter: Financing America’s Schools,” acknowledged this
shift by referring to the adequacy movement in litigation as “Equity II” (Ladd
and Hansen 1999; Minorini and Sugarman 1999a, 1999乙).
桌子 2 summarizes content characteristics of significant court cases for
the time period encompassing the transition from the old education finance
to the modern. From trial testimony and judicial decision content analysis one
can see how expansive both the consideration of courts and expectations for
education finance have become.
The transition from prior considerations of taxpayer and per pupil spend-
ing equity to a new focus on resource sufficiency and system efficiency has
not always been smooth. Court opinions and legislative expectations often
outstrip the current capacity of social science research to deliver satisfying re-
sponses to policy questions (格思里 2004). 此外, whereas education
finance experts once needed to know only about taxation and distribution for-
mulas, now they are expected to be conversant regarding matters as diverse as
achievement testing, teacher qualification, student disabilities, links between
poverty and academic performance, historical evolution of education and ed-
ucation finance, remedial instruction, class size effects, school organization,
instructional strategies, performance incentives, privatization and outsourc-
英, 规模经济, cost function analysis, school governance, 程序
评估, leadership effectiveness, and personnel deployment.
INSIDE THE MODERN EDUCATION FINANCE REFORM PARADIGM
Education financing is now a principal instrument for mediating pursuit of
educational policy and has moved from the periphery of policy-maker concern
to a far more central role. This section describes the two principal school im-
provement or education reform strategies—systemic alignment and economic
dynamics—that have emerged in the past decades to build a foundation for
how the emerging modern education finance has begun to conceptualize link-
ing resources to elevated student academic performance.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
/
F
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
F
.
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
7
8
我
乙
D
U
C
A
时间
氧
氮
F
我
氮
A
氮
C
乙
A
氮
D
磷
氧
L
我
C
是
“
中号
氧
D
乙
右
氮
”
乙
D
U
C
A
时间
我
氧
氮
F
我
氮
A
氮
C
乙
桌子 2 A Quarter-Century Selection of Significant “Old” and “Modern” Education Finance Court Cases Classified by Complaint, Trial Testimony, and Decision Content
Court Case/
Schooling
Facet
Per pupil $ parity Taxpayer equity “Adequate” $ 资源
“At-risk” funding
Class size
Teacher salaries
Teacher qualification
Curriculum standards
Scale economies
Preschool availability
Student achievement
罗宾逊
(新泽西州)
1969
Serrano
(CA)
1972
Seattle
(WA)
1978
Edgewood
(TX)
1989
Rose
(KY)
1989
坎贝尔
(WY)
1994
CFE
(纽约)
2000
West Orange
(TX)
2004
Lakeview
(AR)
2004
Abbeville
(SC)
2005
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
F
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
.
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
James W. 格思里
Systems Alignment
One major reform strategy hinges upon the presence of measurable academic
expectations or curriculum standards and an assortment of instructional and
accountability components aligned in pursuit of these standards. The produc-
tion components in this model involve dimensions such as educator time,
class size (a dimension of teacher time spent with students), instructional
materials and textbooks, student achievement testing, time on learning tasks,
preservice teacher training, parent and community engagement, 领导
训练, personnel and institutional performance reports, professional devel-
选项, in-school peer group characteristics, and in-school and out-of-school
extracurricular activities for students.
This systems-alignment strategy presumes that much regarding good in-
struction is already known and that appropriate coherence between various
instructional components can result in higher levels of student academic
学习. 还, components of this strategy lend themselves to being oper-
ationalized into an instructional alignment measure that can be considered
either as a dependent variable, in an effort to discern policy system condi-
tions providing the greatest or best alignment, or an independent variable, 到
determine alignment consequences for pupil performance.1
Economic Incentives
The other principal reform model takes schooling and instruction to be a
“black box,” perhaps one that is currently impenetrable or unknowable. 三月-
ket and economic incentive advocates contend that a specification of expected
outcomes and an appropriate system for measuring and sanctioning school
success in producing desired student outcomes will productively guide ac-
tions of those inside the black box. Under such assumptions it is less nec-
essary than in a systems-alignment strategy to understand the nature of
throughputs. 然而, it is still crucial to understand the nature of out-
看跌期权. It is also more important to understand interactions of various mar-
ket components (例如, supply; consumer information; performance incentives
for students, 教师, 学校, and districts; competition effects; and market
规定) in the economic-incentive model than in the systems-alignment
模型.
In policy circles competition is often posed as an alternative reform strategy
since market dependence is seen as a major incentive. The ability of clients to
seek different schools, presumably schools more consistent with personal pref-
erences, is taken to be a market incentive to motivate instructional providers.
1.
For more information on means for measuring “alignment” and the metrics involved see Porter
(2002).
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
/
F
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
.
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
9
“MODERN” EDUCATION FINANCE
在本质上, providers either perform to clients’ expectations or lose market
share and accompanying resources.
While it is important to distinguish between these two intervention models
(the sets of tools used to determine their effectiveness overlap partially, 但不是
完全地), a reader should not gain a misimpression that the two models
are mutually exclusive. There are ways by which they can be combined. 为了
例子, an operator of a private school is presumably interested in having
instructional components aligned in order to be effective. Although a systemic
alignment strategy does not preclude reliance upon client choice systems or
performance awards and punishments for teachers or schools in the public
sector, systemic-alignment advocates seldom recommend performance incen-
tives for students, 教师, 学校, or school districts.
RESEARCH AND DATA COLLECTION IN A MODERN EDUCATION
FINANCE ERA
The fulfillment of modern education finance’s quest for elevated outcomes,
pursuit of higher academic standards, means for enhancing instruction, 在-
centives for performance, and desire for greater cost-effectiveness depends
upon superior understanding of research and data collection. 这需要
scholars to be capable of not only integrating new and old education finance
concepts but also forging new paths of inquiry to generate more valid and
reliable conclusions and guide twenty-first century policy-making decisions.
Fusing Modern and Old in Research
There are three categories of recurring research and policy issues that carry
over in part from the old and still stem from modern. These categories, 和
the data needs they portend, are described below.
Equity
Even if the early-twenty-first-century policy pendulum has swung somewhat
away from equity and more forcefully toward sufficiency and efficiency matters,
parity issues remain. There continue to be interests among advocates and ana-
lysts in knowing what schools and districts spend per pupil and what similarly
situated taxpayers and various levels of government and revenue sources con-
tribute toward school spending. 还, revenue and spending figures need to be
informed by inflation, overtime, and by regional cost differences. Classification
of data by student characteristics such as household income level, 种族,
种族, language proficiency, 失能, 年级水平, district type, and school
类型, public or private, all continue as action and policy agenda items.
10
EDUCATION FINANCE AND POLICY
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
/
F
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
.
F
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
James W. 格思里
Adequacy
Discerning the extent to which a finance system provides sufficient opportunity
for students to acquire specified schooling objectives, “adequacy” requires ac-
cess to information regarding student performance, legislated arrangements,
and system resources. Student performance measures should be manifold,
including academic achievement, participation and persistence, and behavior
(discipline). Per pupil spending can be attributed by district, but attribution
by school is even better. (将来, it will probably become important
to have per pupil budgets and accounting.) Also needed are data regarding
characteristics of pupils (种族, household income, language proficiency, 和
失能), regional or geographic cost differences, teacher salary informa-
的, administrative expenditures, instructional supply spending, and a host
of other expenditure objects. Measures of school facilities also are needed. Fi-
nally, determining “adequacy” also necessitates information regarding system
arrangements such as school size and remoteness and state regulations for ac-
tivities such as teacher licensing and pupil, 学校, and district accountability.
Efficiency and Productivity
Determining what instructional programs and arrangements are effective and,
further still, those that are cost-effective requires an ability to link data sets
across performance and resources. Measures of pupil performance must be
associated with resources such as a defined program (例如, reading or mathe-
数学), teacher time, instructional materials, staff development, school and
class size, pupil–professional ratios, teacher characteristics, students’ socioe-
conomic status and other relevant personal and household characteristics,
and bounded program descriptions (expectations, pedagogy, and content) 那
measurably separate one instructional format from another.
Modern Education Finance Research and Data Collection Needs
Principal differences in data collection and research demands, when contrasted
with conventional finance predecessors, occur on five dimensions. The graphic
model in Figure 1 depicts education system processes and highlights new data
items that need to be unraveled to promote a more fine-grained understanding
of schools within the modern education finance paradigm. Space is insufficient
here to undertake an exhaustive description of each of these dimensions;
然而, 图中 1 we have illustrated each.
Knowledge of Production
More complete modeling techniques and enhanced knowledge of instruc-
的, 操作, and organizational strategies are needed to realize modern
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
F
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
F
.
.
.
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
11
“MODERN” EDUCATION FINANCE
数字 1
Expansion
of Outcome
Measures
知识
的
Production
“Modern”
教育
Finance
研究
Paradigm
Expansion
of Units of
分析
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
F
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
知识
of Market
Dynamics
知识
of Systemic
Alignment
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
F
.
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
Needed Components and Interactions for “Modern” Education Finance Research Paradigm
education finance’s call for understanding relationships between educational
输入, throughputs, and outputs. For many years scholars have relied on tra-
ditional education production forms that depend on repurposed production
attributes from the private manufacturing sector, where known ratios of inputs
to outputs exist (看, 例如, Cohn and Geske 1990; Betts 1996; Monk
and Rice 1999). Education is a multiproduct enterprise where technology used
to produce different attributes may not permit aggregation, thus necessitat-
ing that each outcome has a separate or individual production function. 作为
一个结果, complexity of “real” education production function is at the mercy
of the spectrum of characteristics embedded in the “raw material” (学生)
available to “producers” (学校).
12
EDUCATION FINANCE AND POLICY
James W. 格思里
It is probable that a schooling production function is highly individu-
alized and presently resides in an unstable black box comprising multiple
idiosyncratic interactions between, and characteristics possessed by, individ-
ual teachers and individual students. As Guthrie and Rothstein (1999) 著名的,
models lacking any recognition of education-relevant production components
that can be reasonably presumed or empirically proved to enhance students’
技能, 知识, and capacity development can tell us only what resource
levels were generally associated with acceptable achievement (with inefficient
practices removed, to the extent known), not what resource level would be
必要的, if used efficiently, for this outcome.
Expanded Outcome Measures
Policy relevant outcome measures depend crucially upon one or many quantifi-
able variables or proxies closely paralleling and encompassing characteristics
embodied in a desired production outcome. A great majority of studies, 为了
例子, rely on some combination of standardized achievement test scores
as an outcome measure. 然而, test scores are “potentially noisy and un-
stable measures” (Ballou 2002, p. 12) that may catch only a narrow swath of
education system purpose.
Most state statutes list tens of other desired cognitive and noncognitive
结果. 这些包括, 例如, performance dimensions such as citi-
禅宗, 音乐, 艺术, physical fitness, patriotism, personal honesty, and punc-
tuality. Though recent research is beginning to examine causal relationships
between educational attainment and such education-related outcomes as cit-
主权 (Milligan, Moretti, and Oreopoulos 2004; Dee and Levine 2004),
standardized test scores are not understood sufficiently to be assumed appro-
priate for capturing our education system’s whole intent when influencing
contemporary policy decisions. 因此, it is imperative that more complete
outcome measures that more accurately reflect the broader intent of education
are collected.
Knowledge of Education Market Dynamics
One of the two previously referenced major reform strategies, market dynam-
集成电路, requires yet a different kind of information to measure its effectiveness.
In addition to most of the aforementioned measures regarding pupils, 房子-
holds, and resources, choice necessitates measures of supply and competition.
These involve private and public providers and competition classifications of
schools regarding charter, magnet, or “attendance geographically restricted”
地位.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
F
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
.
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
13
“MODERN” EDUCATION FINANCE
Summary
Data collection can be expensive. 然而, direct costs are seldom the ex-
pensive part of the undertaking. Actual incremental costs of a data collection
effort are infrequently more than a few tenths of a percent of total education
operational spending, even when student academic testing is put into the cost
方程 (我们. General Accounting Office 2004). Larger costs are associated
with transactions and local, 状态, and other school-affiliated officials’ time
when asked to comply with requests for information. It is the multitiered gov-
ernmental mosaic relied upon by the United States to operate its schools that
exacerbates transactional expenses. The possible (mis)perception by informa-
tion suppliers that requested data are of little or no value to them in their
or their institutions’ immediate operation adds to the burden and sometimes
distorts the validity of the data collected.
Some data are needed for administrative oversight and legal compliance
(例如, minimal teacher salaries and percent of local district budget spent on
instruction and administration). Where such administratively required in-
formation is also useful for research and analytic purposes, then marginal
collection costs are low. It is when data providers are seldom end users that
incremental collection costs are intensified and accuracy is stretched. 这些
成本, both financial and psychological, necessitate an efficient data collection
手术.
结论
Total costs for America’s public schools have risen to almost $3 billion an
operating day; and as a result, the policy community anticipates that education
finance is becoming a lever, manipulation of which might maximize education
system purposes. This is the backdrop and principal propellant behind the
increasing policy system insistence that resources be linked with outcomes. 它
is this linkage that is shaping “modern” education finance.
The author wishes to express appreciation to Mathew G. Springer for his assistance in
the preparation of this essay.
参考
Ballou, 戴尔. 2002. Sizing up test scores. Education Next 2 (2): 10–15.
本森, C. S. 1965. The cheerful prospect: A statement of the future of American education.
波士顿: Houghton Mifflin.
Betts, G. 1996. Does money matter? The effect of school resources on student achievement
and adult success. 华盛顿, 直流: 布鲁金斯学会出版社.
Campaign for Fiscal Equity (CFE) v. 状态. 2003. 不. 74. Accessed 16 八月 2005.
Available http://www.schoolfunding.info/states/ny/6–27–03Victory.php3.
14
EDUCATION FINANCE AND POLICY
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
F
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
.
.
.
F
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
James W. 格思里
Campbell v. State of Wyoming (Campbell I). 1995. 不. 907 P.2d 1238, LEXIS
203. Accessed 22 八月 2005. Available http://www.schoolfunding.info/states/wy/
lit wy.php3.
坎贝尔, J。, 右. Hombo, 和 J. Mazzeo. 2000. NAEP 1999 trends in academic progress:
Three decades of student performance. 华盛顿, 直流: 我们. 教育部-
的, Office of Educational Research and Improvement, National Center for Education
统计数据.
Cohn, E., 和T. G. Geske. 1990. The economics of education. 3RD版. 牛津, England:
Butterworth–Heinemann.
Dee, Thomas S., and Jeffrey Levine. 2004. The fate of new funding: 证据来自
Massachusetts’ education finance reform. Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis
26 (3): 199–215.
格思里, James W. 2004. Twenty-first century education finance: Equity, adequacy,
and the emerging challenge of linking resources to performance. In Money, 政治,
and law: Intersections and conflicts in the provision of educational opportunity, edited by
K. K. Wong and K. DeMoss. Poughkeepsie, 纽约: Eye on Education, PP. 1–15.
格思里, James W., and Richard Rothstein. 1999. Enabling “adequacy” to achieve
现实: Translating adequacy into state school finance distribution arrangements. 在
Equity and adequacy in education finance: Issues and perspectives, edited by Helen F. Ladd,
Rosemary Chalk, and Janet S. 汉森. 华盛顿, 直流: National Academy Press,
PP. 209–59.
Ladd, Helen F., and Janet S. 汉森. 1999. Making money matter: Financing America’s
学校. 华盛顿, 直流: National Academy Press.
Lakeview School District, 不. 25 v. Huckabee. 2001. 不. 1992–5318. Accessed 15 八月
2005. Available http://www.schoolfunding.info/states/ar/lit ar.php3.
Milligan, K., 乙. Moretti, 和P. Oreopoulos. 2004. Does education improve citizenship?
Evidence from the U.S. and the U.K. 公共经济学杂志 88 (9–10): 1667–95.
Minorini, 磷. A。, 和S. D. Sugarman. 1999A. Educational adequacy and the courts:
The promise and problems of moving to a new paradigm. In Equity and adequacy in
education finance: Issues and perspectives, edited by Helen F. Ladd, Rosemary Chalk, 和
Janet S. 汉森. 华盛顿, 直流: National Academy Press, PP. 175–208.
Minorini, 磷. A。, 和S. D. Sugarman. 1999乙. School finance litigation in the name of
education equity: Its evolution, impact, and future. In Equity and adequacy in education
finance: Issues and perspectives, edited by Helen F. Ladd, Rosemary Chalk, and Janet S.
汉森. 华盛顿, 直流: National Academy Press, PP. 34–71.
Monk, David H., and Jennifer King Rice. 1999. Modern education productivity re-
搜索: Emerging implications for the financing of education. In Selected papers in
school finance, 1997–1999, edited by W. Fowler Jr. 华盛顿, 直流: 我们. Department
of Education, 国家教育统计中心 1999-134, PP. 111–39.
National Commission on Excellence in Education. 1983. A nation at risk: The imperative
for educational reform. 华盛顿, 直流: 我们. 教育部.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
F
/
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
.
.
F
.
.
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
15
“MODERN” EDUCATION FINANCE
Porter, Andrew C. 2002. Measuring the content of instruction: Uses in research and
实践. Educational Researcher 37 (7): 3–14.
Rose v. Council for Better Education. 1989. 790 S.W.2d. 186, 60 Ed. Law Rep. Accessed
11 八月 2005. Available http://www.wcer.wisc.edu/cpre/finance/state/ky/case/asp.
史密斯, 中号. S。, 和 J. O’Day. 1991. Systemic school reform. In The politics of curriculum
and testing: 这 1990 yearbook of the Politics of Education Association, edited by S. H.
Fuhrman and B. Malen. 布里斯托尔, PA: Falmer, PP. 233–67.
我们. General Accounting Office (GAO). 2004. Unfunded mandates: Analysis of Reform
Act coverage. Report to the chairman, Subcommittee on Oversight of Government
管理, the Federal Workforce, and the District of Columbia, Committee on
Government Affairs, 我们. Senate. 华盛顿, 直流: GAO. Accessed 16 八月 2005.
Available http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d04637.pdf.
Vinovski, 中号. 1996. An analysis of the concept and uses of systemic educational reform.
American Educational Research Journal 33:53–85.
Webb, F. R。, 中号. V. Covington, 和 J. 瓦. 格思里. 1993. Creating prescriptions for
success in urban schools: Turning the corner on pathological explanations for academic
failure. In Motivating students to learn: Overcoming barriers to high achievement, edited by
时间. 中号. Tomlinson. 伯克利, CA: McCutchan, Chapter 5.
West Orange-Cove Consolidated ISD v. 纳尔逊. 2001. 不. GV1-00528. Accessed 15 八月
2005. Available http://www.schoolfunding.info/states/tx/lit tx.php3.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
F
/
/
e
d
你
e
d
p
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
1
3
1
6
9
2
9
9
1
e
d
p
2
0
0
6
1
1
3
p
d
F
.
.
.
.
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
16
EDUCATION FINANCE AND POLICY
下载pdf