Misallocation, Access to Finance, and Public
Credit: Firm-Level Evidence
∗
MIGUEL A. LE ´ON-LEDESMA AND DIMITRIS CHRISTOPOULOS
Using a database of 23,000 firms in 45 经济体, we test the quantitative
importance of access to finance and access to public and private credit for the
determination of misallocation. We first derive measures of factor market and
size distortions, and then use these measures within a regression framework to
test the significance of self-declared access-to-finance obstacles as well as the
effect of access to a credit line issued by either a government-owned or private
bank. We find that access-to-finance obstacles and private credit increase the
dispersion of distortions. Public credit has a very small effect. For firms that do
not face financial obstacles, public credit increases the dispersion of distortions;
for firms that face financial obstacles, it slightly decreases dispersion. 民众
credit does not appear to compensate for the distortions that exist in private
credit markets. Quantitatively, 然而, financial variables explain a very small
part of the dispersion of factor market and size distortions.
关键词: financial access, firm level, misallocation, 生产率, public credit
JEL codes: O40, O43, O47
我. 介绍
Recent literature has emphasized the role of misallocation in determining total
factor productivity (TFP) differences between economies. Misallocation implies that
aggregate TFP could be higher given the same amount of capital, 劳动, and firm-level
TFP. Because of distortions that prevent factors of production from being allocated
for their best use, firms with high productivity may be too small and firms with low
productivity may be too large, leading to a fall in aggregate (weighted) TFP. 之一
the key distortions that may cause misallocation is the existence of financial access
problems that generate quantity constraints and price dispersion in credit markets. 在
order to bypass these financial access distortions, governments often resort to public
policies for the allocation of credit through government-owned credit institutions.
∗Miguel Le´on–Ledesma (corresponding author): School of Economics and Macroeconomics, 生长, 和
History Centre, University of Kent, 英国. 电子邮件: M.A.Leon-Ledesma@kent.ac.uk; Dimitris
Christopoulos: Department of Economic and Regional Development, Panteion University, 雅典, 希腊. 电子邮件:
christod@panteion.gr. The authors would like to thank the participants at the Asian Development Outlook–Asian
Development Review Conference held in Seoul in November 2015, the managing editor, and an anonymous referee
for helpful comments. They would also like to thank Alessandro Cusimano and Daniel Roland for excellent research
协助. The usual disclaimer applies. ADB recognizes “China” as the People’s Republic of China.
Asian Development Review, 卷. 33, 不. 2, PP. 119–143
C(西德:3) 2016 Asian Development Bank
and Asian Development Bank Institute
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
120 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
在本文中, we test empirically the quantitative importance of
access-to-finance obstacles, access to public and private credit, and their interaction,
for the determination of the dispersion of distortions. Using a database of around
23,000 firms in 45 经济体, we first derive measures of factor market and
size distortions from the theoretical framework proposed by Hsieh and Klenow
(2009).1 In this framework, the dispersion of distortions determines the degree
of misallocation, and thus TFP losses, at the aggregate level. 然后我们使用这些
distortion measures and, within a regression framework, test the significance of
self-declared access-to-finance obstacles as well as the effect of access to a credit
line issued by either a government-owned or private bank. Since selection to receive
a public and/or private credit line may be endogenous, we instrumentalize these
变量. 然后, using a factor representation of the regression results, we obtain
a decomposition of the contribution of these variables to the dispersion of factor
market and size distortions in order to assess whether these variables increased or
decreased the dispersion of observed distortions.
Our key results are as follows. Access-to-finance obstacles increase the
dispersion of both factor market distortions and size distortions. Private credit
also significantly increases the dispersion of both distortions, 尤其是
size distortion. This is an expected result since the existence of informational
asymmetries in underdeveloped financial markets can lead to an inefficient allocation
of private credit. Public credit, 另一方面, has a very small effect. For firms that
do not face financial obstacles, it increases slightly the dispersion of both distortions.
For firms that face financial obstacles, it decreases slightly the dispersion, 但事实并非如此
significant in the case of size distortions. Public credit does not appear to compensate
for the distortions that exist in private credit markets. 全面的, 然而, a large part
of the dispersion of distortions remains unexplained. Financial variables appear
important only in driving the explained part of these distortions and are significant.
Quantitatively, they explain too small part of them to be considered as the key drivers
of misallocation.
Our study only looks at the effects of these variables through the misallocation
channel and not through other direct channels that affect productivity and capital
积累. 还, we are only looking at the misallocation effects and ignoring the
cost of setting up and running government-owned credit institutions and the cost of
subsidizing credit through taxes. In this respect, our study uncovers another channel
through which credit policies can affect aggregate outcomes. 尽管如此, it is an
important one given the potential TFP gains from reallocation. Government-owned
credit
institutions are common in many emerging markets and imply costly
运营. Banks such as the China Development Bank in the People’s Republic
of China (PRC), the Brazilian Development Bank and Caixa Economica in Brazil,
1The total number of economies in the sample is 45. In many of the empirical measures, 然而, 经济体
are dropped due to the unavailability of certain variables.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 121
Bancoldex in Colombia, and a large number of state-owned banks in India are
examples of the proliferation of credit institutions with an important element of
government ownership and/or explicit development goals.
A.
Related Literature
Our paper is related mainly to two strands of existing literature. 一方面,
there is a growing body of theoretical and empirical literature on misallocation. 在
另一方面, there is a strand of literature analyzing the effects of public credit and
development banks. The role of misallocation has been emphasized in the seminal
works of Hopenhayn (1992) and Hopenhayn and Rogerson (1993), with further
contributions from Banerjee and Duflo (2005); Restuccia and Rogerson (2008);
Guner, Ventura, and Xu (2008); and Bartelsman, Haltiwanger, and Scarpetta (2013).
An important work for our research is Hsieh and Klenow (2009), which develops a
method to measure how distortions at the micro level imply aggregate TFP losses
and uses this method to quantify TFP losses in the PRC and India relative to the
美国 (我们). Their findings show that, had the PRC and India had similar
levels of misallocation to the US, their TFP would be between 30% 和 60% 更高,
分别. Kalemli–Ozcan and Sorensen (2012) use a similar approach to ours by
investigating the role of access to finance for misallocation in African economies.
然而, they do not analyze the effect on the dispersion of distortions or focus on
the role of private and public credit.
The role of distortions to capital and credit markets in determining
misallocation has attracted increasing interest in recent years. Midrigan and Xu
(2014) report that the dispersion of the marginal product of capital is of an order
of magnitude several times larger than that for the marginal products of labor
and intermediate inputs. 此外, this dispersion is very persistent, 哪个
implies that capital adjustment costs cannot be the sole source of misallocation.
Since financial systems channel funds from less to more productive projects,
a lack of financial development can hinder TFP. Banerjee and Duflo (2005),
例如, provide evidence on the role of credit constraints and other credit
market imperfections in misallocation and, 因此, productivity differences across
经济体. 然而,
the literature on the relationship between finance and
misallocation is far from settled. Moll (2014) shows that in a simple setting where
firms face collateral constraints `a la Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), if productivity
shocks are persistent, then misallocation losses can be large and disappear only
slowly. 另一方面, they are unimportant in steady state. 这是因为
firms facing persistent shocks can use self-financing as a form of insurance against
incomplete access to credit markets. Banerjee and Moll (2010) argue, 然而, 那
misallocation can still exist in steady state at the extensive rather than intensive
margin (through the firm entry and exit channel). Buera, Kaboski, and Shin (2011),
using a quantitative model with financial frictions, find that they account for around
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
122 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
50% of TFP gaps between economies. The mechanism is that firms with larger
scales of operations are more productive and have more financing needs, 因此
financial frictions affect them disproportionately. 然而, Midrigan and Xu (2014),
using firm-level data for the Republic of Korea, find that financial frictions have
a quantitatively small effect on misallocation. This is consistent with the micro
evidence reviewed by Udry (2011), who finds that financial constraints do not play
a dominant role in determining misallocation.
Our paper also relates to the literature on the role of public credit and
government-owned banks for development. Early empirical literature such as La
Porta, Lopez de Silanes, and Shleifer (2002) find a negative effect of public
ownership of banks on subsequent productivity growth. Carvalho (2014), 使用
firm-level data for Brazil, finds that public credit is directed to shifting employment
toward politically attractive areas before elections. Ribeiro and de Negri (2009),
using firm-level data for firms accessing credit from the Brazilian Development
Bank, find very limited effects of public credit on TFP levels and growth. Banerjee
and Duflo (2014) use a policy change in India that modified eligibility for directed
credit and find that public credit was used to expand economic activity rather than
substitute for other forms of credit. This is interpreted as evidence that firms were
credit constrained before accessing public credit. Eslava, Maffioli, and Mel´endez
(2014) also find that access to financing from a nontargeted, unsubsidized program
of Bancoldex in Colombia had positive effects on employment and investment,
especially for long-term lending. Using a heterogeneous-agents model calibrated
to the US and Brazil, Antunes, Cavalcanti, and Villamil (2015) find that credit
subsidy policies have no effect on output and almost no aggregate effects. Our paper
complements this literature by providing a direct empirical analysis of the effect
of credit policies on productivity through the misallocation channel for a large
number of economies. Our findings are consistent with previous results. 民众
credit reduces misallocation only for financially constrained firms that face financial
obstacles. 然而, it increases misallocation for the rest and, on aggregate, 这
total effect is very small.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II presents the theoretical
framework used to derive distortions from the data. Section III discusses the
econometric methodology. Section IV presents and describes the data. Section V
presents the results. Section VI concludes.
二. Measuring Distortions
In Hsieh and Klenow (2009), misallocation arises as a consequence of
distortions or wedges that affect heterogeneous firms in an idiosyncratic manner.
These wedges, which are akin to taxes, prevent heterogeneous firms from achieving
their optimal size, thereby leading to aggregate TFP losses. 以下, we briefly explain
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 123
the quantitative measures of distortions proposed by Hsieh and Klenow (2009),
which we will use later in the empirical analysis.
There are s = 1, . . . , S sectors and Ms firms within each of the S industries.
The total final output in sector s (Ys), is a Dixit–Stiglitz aggregator of the output
produced by each firm (Ysi):
Ys =
(西德:2)
Ms(西德:3)
我=1
(西德:4) σ
σ −1
σ −1
σ
是
si
(1)
where σ is the elasticity of substitution between varieties. Each firm’s production
function is given by a Cobb–Douglas aggregator of capital (K) and labor (L), 和
individual firm’s TFP given by Asi :2
Ysi = Asi K
si L 1−αs
作为
si
(2)
There are two distortions or wedges affecting firms. One that affects output or firm
尺寸 (τy,si ), and another that affects relative factor inputs (τk,si ). Since it is not
possible to separately identify wedges that affect capital and labor, we choose to
impose the wedge on capital, but this is to be interpreted as a distortion that affects
the relative price of capital and labor. As these wedges are firm specific, they will
not affect all firms the same way, thus generating differences in capital–labor ratios
between firms. With these wedges, the problem of the firm is to choose between K
and L to maximize profits (πsi ):
πsi = max
K ,L
[(1 − τy,si )Psi Ysi − wL si − (1 + τk,si )R Ksi ]
(3)
where P is the price of the final good, w is the wage rate, and R is the rental price of
首都. Since factor markets are competitive, all firms face the same factor prices.
Using the first-order conditions for capital and labor, substituting them in the
production function and finding the optimal price for each variety yields the standard
result that price is a markup over marginal costs: Psi = σ
Asi (1−τy,si ) .
1−σ
With this pricing rule, the quantities of labor demanded and the quantity of output
produced by each firm are proportional to their individual TFP and the idiosyncratic
distortions or wedges they face. In the absence of distortions, firms’ relative shares
1−α (1+τk,si )A
w
1−αs
(西德:6)A(西德:5)
右
作为
(西德:5)
(西德:6)
2The Cobb–Douglas assumption is not innocuous. If the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor
differs from 1, then the dispersion of the marginal product of capital, and hence the gains from reallocation, 能
change substantially. The more that capital and labor are substitutes for one another, the more technologically similar
they are and the less important relative factor market distortions will be. Recent evidence suggests that this elasticity
significantly differs from unity (看, 例如, Le´on–Ledesma, McAdam, and Willman 2010, 2015).
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
124 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
of output and labor would just be a function of Ai. The capital–labor ratio is given
经过
Ksi
L si
=
作为
1 − αs
w
右
1
1 + τk,si
(4)
which implies that the idiosyncratic factor market distortion prevents firms from
equalizing their capital–labor ratios.
The marginal revenue product of capital is given by MRPKsi = Psi MPKsi .
Given the definition of MPK, we obtain
MRPKsi = αs
σ − 1
σ
Psi Ysi
Ksi
= R
1 + τk,si
1 − τy,si
(5)
同样地, TFP revenue (TFPR) is defined as TFPRsi = Psi Asi , 哪个, 使用
the definition of prices, yields
TFPRsi =
σ
σ − 1
(西德:7)
右
作为
(西德:8)作为
(西德:7)
(西德:8)
w
1 − αs
1−αs (1 + τk,si )A
(西德:6)
(西德:5)
1 − τy,si
(6)
From equations (5) 和 (6) 多于, it is clear that, in the absence of distortions,
marginal revenue products of capital and TFPRsi would equalize across firms. 如果
a firm has a relatively high Ai, it will attract more capital and labor, until its
price falls such that its TFPRsi equalizes with that of lower productivity firms.
因此, as discussed below, the dispersion of MRPKsi and/or TFPRsi is a measure of
idiosyncratic distortions affecting firm sizes.
It is also possible to obtain independent measures of size and factor market
distortions, which are the ones we will work with as they allow us to separate the
effects of access to finance and public credit by type of distortion. From equation
(4), we get
1 + τk,si =
作为
1 − αs
wL si
R Ksi
and combining this with (5), we find
1 − τy,si =
σ
σ − 1
wL si
(1 − αs) Psi Ysi
(7)
(8)
因此, the factor market distortion measures the firm’s relative cost share of
labor and capital relative to that for the sector represented by αs/(1 − αs). The size
distortion measures the cost share of labor for the firm relative to that for the sector
给出的 (1 − αs).
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 125
What we observe in the data are the MRPKsi and TFPRsi (and not the MPKsi
and TFPsi) for every firm as we do not observe individual firm prices. This is why
Hsieh and Klenow (2009) make an assumption about market structure to infer prices
as a function of firm productivity and distortions.
Aggregate TFP in any sector s is defined as TFPR over aggregate prices.
Using the final product aggregator, we obtain
TFPs = TFPRs
Ps
=
(西德:2)
Ms(西德:3)
⎡
⎣
我=1
Asi
TFPRs
TFPRsi
(西德:4)σ −1
1
σ −1
⎤
⎦
(9)
where TFPR is the weighted average of TFPR for all firms in the sector. If all firms
were the same (no heterogeneity), the ratio in brackets would disappear. At this point,
sectoral (and aggregate) TFP is maximized.3 That is, aggregate TFP is maximized
when there is no dispersion in TFPRsi. Since by equation (6) the dispersion of TFPR
is driven by the dispersion of distortions, then zero dispersion in both factor market
and size distortions would imply maximum sectoral TFP.
三、. 方法
Our aim is to uncover the effect of financial access and access to public
and private credit on the two measures of firm-level distortions derived from the
model used by Hsieh and Klenow (2009): 日志(1 + τk,si ), and log(1 − τy,si ).4 自从
misallocation depends on the distribution of these measures, we are also interested
in uncovering the effect of these variables on their dispersion. 这样做, we proceed
as follows. We first regress the two measures of distortions on variables measuring
financial access, variables measuring access to public credit and private credit, 和
a set of controls. We will also interact the credit variables with the access-to-finance
variables to show whether public and private credit have a different effect for firms
that face financial access difficulties. If these variables are not important in affecting
the distribution of distortions, they will not be significant. In order to measure
whether the different variables increase or decrease the dispersion of distortions,
we then use a Fields (2003) 分解, which we explain below in more detail.
This decomposition also allows us to understand better the role of financial variables
as some coefficients are not directly interpretable in the initial regressions when we
use an instrumental variables approach.
(西德:13)
Y =
3In Hsieh and Klenow (2009), the final economy’s output is a Cobb–Douglas aggregator of sectoral outputs
S Y θS
4在等式中 (12), we ignore the first term driven by the demand elasticity for the different varieties as it drops
, where θS represents sector shares.
s
as a constant.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
126 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
Specifically, for the more general case with interaction terms, we run the
following cross-sectional regression:
log Di = β0 + β1FAi + β2PUBi + β3PRIVi + β4FAi × PUBi +
β5FAi × PRIVi + Xi B + εi
(10)
where Di represents the distortion of interest; FAi is a self-reported financial access
difficulty binary variable taking the value of 1 if the firm faces financial obstacles and
zero otherwise; PUBi is a binary variable taking the value of 1 if the firm has access
to public credit and zero otherwise; PRIVi is, similarly, a binary variable for private
credit; and Xi is a vector of control variables that includes economy and sector
dummies, and other variables.5 The coefficients β1 to β3 give us the direct effect of
financial variables, while β4 and β5 show how the effect of public and private credit
changes when the firm faces financial obstacles. A positive coefficient for the factor
market distortion implies that the wedge increases for capital relative to labor. 为了
the size distortion, a positive coefficient implies that the variable reduces the wedge
and acts as a size subsidy in the sense that the firm’s labor share is higher than
the average for its sector. Financial constraints can have either positive or negative
effects on size distortions depending on how they affect the activities of the firm.
Financial constraints may lead to lower labor costs if firms need working capital to
pay wages, or to higher costs if they distort the relative use of capital and labor in
the firm given an elasticity of substitution between them.
As explained above, if these variables appear to be significant, then they are
drivers of misallocation. 然而, looking at the coefficients by themselves does not
inform us whether these variables lead to an increase or a decrease in the dispersion
of distortions. 这样做, we look at the Fields (2003) 分解, which is based
on previous contributions by Shorrocks (1982). This decomposition has been used
widely in the labor literature to analyze the dispersion of outcome variables such as
wages and earnings that can be explained by regressor variables such as education,
年龄, 和性别. In our case, we analyze the effect of the different financial variables
on the dispersion of the explained part of distortions. We can estimate equation (10)
by using ordinary least squares (OLS) or instrumental variable (IV). The resulting
predicted distortion can be written as a factor model:
日志 (西德:14)Di = β0 + ˆz1 + ˆz2 + ··· + ˆzk
(11)
where a hat over a variable denotes its predicted value and ˆz j = ˆβ j X j for j = 1, . . . ,
k regressors. The Fields (2003) decomposition exploits this factor structure to study
the effect of the composite variables ˆz j on the dispersion of the explained part of the
5We also experimented using year dummies to control for the year the survey was implemented. The results,
然而, were not affected by their inclusion.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 127
失真. 那是, it will tell us the percentage increase or decrease in the dispersion
of the predicted distortion that is explained by each of the regressors. This allows
us to assess the effect of financial variables on misallocation directly.
The main problem with estimating equation (10) by OLS is that access to
public or private credit may not be an exogenous treatment. Receiving credit from
both types of institutions may depend on unobserved factors that also affect observed
distortions, leading to correlation between the credit variables and the error term.
为此原因, we also run regressions instrumentalizing both the PUBi and PRIVi
binary variables.6 In order to do so, we first run a probit model where we project
the variables on a set of instruments plus the controls. 我们不可以, 然而, use the
fitted values of this regression on a second stage due to the problem of “forbidden
regression” as explained by Angrist and Pischke (2009). This happens because the
conditional expectation function of the first stage is nonlinear. To get around this
问题, we follow Wooldridge (2010) and proceed using the following steps:
(我) Estimate a probit of the determinants of the credit variables using a set of
instruments hi and the control variables Xi . Obtain the fitted values (西德:15)圆周率 .
(二) Regress Pi on (西德:15)Pi and the control variables Xi , not on the instruments. Obtain
the second-stage fitted values
(西德:15)(西德:15)磷.
(三、) Regress Di on Xi and the second-stage fitted values
(西德:15)(西德:15)圆周率 .
自从
(西德:15)(西德:15)P now comes from an OLS regression, the problem of the nonlinear
conditional expectation function has been eliminated. In our case, 然而, we also
have interaction terms between FAi and the two instrumentalized credit variables.
Interaction variables also suffer from the same forbidden regression problem
上文提到的. In order to address this, we follow a similar procedure. 我们
run a first-stage probit and obtain (西德:15)圆周率 . We then calculate (西德:15)Pi × FAi . We regress
(西德:2)(西德:15)Pi × FAi . We then
Pi × FAi on (西德:15)Pi × FAi and the exogenous controls to obtain
(西德:2)(西德:15)Pi × FAi , and the other controls. 这给出了
regress the distortion variables on
us consistent standard errors and unbiased estimates and allows us to carry out
the Fields (2003) 分解. The coefficients on the instrumentalized variables
cannot be interpreted the same way as the coefficients of the original binary variables
since they are now continuous. 然而, the decomposition of the dispersion of the
distortions still has the same interpretation. This is the added advantage of this
分解.
(西德:15)(西德:15)圆周率 ,
6The financial access variable is a self-declared variable in the survey. Since there is no a priori reason for
firms to declare financial access difficulties to surveyors, we believe it is safe to treat it as exogenous.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
128 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
IV. Data and Descriptive Statistics
We use firm-level survey data from the World Bank’s Enterprise Surveys
for the period 2006–2014. This is a stratified survey of firms containing financial
and business environment information. The data are purely cross-sectional. 一些
economies have been surveyed more than once during the review period, so we keep
the data for the survey year with more available observations in order not to bias the
results by weighting some economies twice. The original data contains results from
134 surveys and a total of 61,669 firms. 然而, this number was considerably
reduced in the data-cleaning process (described below) and because of the lack of
availability of some of the credit variables required in the analysis. Since we do
not have price data for each firm, we are working with revenue-based measures as
discussed in the model used by Hsieh and Klenow (2009). Data are in local currency
units for the survey year. We do not transform them into a common currency since
the measures we use are ratios and shares rather than absolute values. We calculate
the variables of interest as follows:
(我) Output is measured as value added (VA). This is calculated as total annual
sales minus the cost of raw materials and intermediate goods.
(二) The number of workers (L) is the total number of full-time employees adjusted
for temporary workers.
(三、) 首都 (K) is defined as the net book value of machinery, equipment, 土地,
and buildings.
(四号) Total wage bill (WTOT) corresponds to total wages, salaries, and bonuses
paid.
(v) Labor productivity is VA/L.
We drop firms for which either VA, K, or WTOT are negative. We are then
left with 23,023 firms and 45 经济体. We also dropped any economy for which
there are less than 150 firms in the sample. In many of the specifications used below,
然而, the lack of availability of some of the credit variables and variables used as
instruments in the first-stage probit regressions leaves us with approximately 14,800
firms.
桌子 1 presents the list of economies, the number of firms, 和他们的
distribution by size when we use the sample of 23,023 firms for 45 经济体.
Size is defined as “small” for firms with fewer than 20 雇员, “medium” for
firms with between 20 和 99 雇员, and “large” for firms with more than 100
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 129
桌子 1. Number of Firms and Size Distribution
Distribution by Number
of Employees (比率)
Small Medium Large
(>100)
(20−100)
(<20)
No.
No.
247
965
272
172
197
875
472
401
438
Angola
Argentina
Bangladesh
Bolivia
Brazil
Bulgaria
Chile
PRC
Colombia
Costa Rica
Croatia
Ecuador
Egypt
El Salvador
Ghana
Guatemala
Honduras
India
Indonesia
Iraq
Jordan
Kenya
Lao PDR
173
532
1,039
198
925
362
572
1,327
545
172
209
222
1,299
282
261
244
184
4,586
536
452
234
208
311
0.85
0.25
0.28
0.47
0.34
0.31
0.30
0.13
0.33
0.34
0.34
0.41
0.38
0.35
0.64
0.40
0.52
0.29
0.46
0.76
0.39
0.27
0.47
209
644
231
228
236
265
424
253
245
159
595
279
343
23,023
Lao PDR = Lao People’s Democratic Republic, PRC = People’s Republic of China.
Source: Authors’ compilation.
Zambia
Zimbabwe
Total
Federation
Peru
Philippines
0.02 Mali
0.35 Mexico
0.35 Mozambique
0.15 Nepal
0.21 Nicaragua
0.22 Nigeria
0.30
0.44
0.31 Russian
0.22
Senegal
0.33
South Africa
0.22
Sri Lanka
0.22
Sweden
0.28
Tanzania
0.11
Tunisia
0.23
0.18
Turkey
0.25 Uganda
0.25 Ukraine
0.01 Uruguay
0.28 Viet Nam
0.36
0.17
0.13
0.40
0.38
0.37
0.45
0.47
0.41
0.43
0.36
0.44
0.33
0.37
0.40
0.37
0.26
0.37
0.30
0.46
0.29
0.23
0.33
0.38
0.36
Distribution by Number
of Employees (ratio)
Small Medium Large
(>100)
(20−100)
(<20)
0.79
0.33
0.63
0.32
0.59
0.68
0.24
0.22
0.36
0.76
0.34
0.51
0.28
0.49
0.18
0.23
0.58
0.47
0.45
0.14
0.46
0.35
0.36
0.19
0.34
0.31
0.47
0.34
0.28
0.40
0.47
0.41
0.17
0.40
0.29
0.52
0.35
0.45
0.41
0.35
0.35
0.45
0.41
0.37
0.38
0.39
0.02
0.33
0.06
0.21
0.07
0.04
0.36
0.31
0.23
0.07
0.26
0.20
0.21
0.17
0.37
0.36
0.07
0.18
0.10
0.45
0.17
0.27
0.25
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
.
/
employees. There are nine Asian economies in the sample. The sample is dominated
by Bangladesh, the PRC, Egypt, and India. While the sample mainly comprises
small and medium firms, large firms represent a sizable 25% of the total. Given the
prevalence of small firms in these economies, large firms may be overrepresented.
The World Bank argues that this is the case since larger firms tend to have a larger
impact on employment creation.
The credit and access-to-finance variables also come from the surveys.
Firms were asked to answer the following question: “How much of an obstacle
is financial access for the operation of the firm?” Firms then choose between
“no obstacle,” “minor obstacle,” “moderate obstacle,” “major obstacle,” and “very
severe obstacle.” We translate these into a numeric, binomial variable taking the
value of zero for no obstacle, minor, and moderate obstacle; and 1 for major and
very severe obstacle. We also do a robustness check by classifying moderate obstacle
as 1 rather than zero. This variable is used as a measure of financial access obstacles
(FAi ), which will then be interacted with indicators of the type of credit available.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
130 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
Firms were also asked whether they currently have a line of credit. If so, they
were asked the following question: “Is this credit provided by a state-owned bank
or a private credit bank?” We use these variables as a proxy for access to public and
private credit, which are our PUBi and PRIVi variables, respectively. Ideally, such
variable should account for the amount of the firm’s capital financed by both types
of institutions. However, this measure is only available for a very small number of
firms. Thus, this variable is taken as a proxy for being able to access either type
of credit. The variables public credit (PUBi ) and private credit (PRIVi ) are binary
variables that take the value of 1 if firms have access to a public or a private line of
credit and zero otherwise.
infrastructure (transportation, electricity); goods markets
We also use a set of control variables related to other types of obstacles to
the operation of firms. These obstacles are measured as binary variables just like
the access-to-credit variable. These obstacles can be classified into the following
categories:
(trade
regulations, informal sector); taxation and licensing; insecurity (political instability,
corruption, theft, corruption, and courts); and labor markets (regulations and skill
inadequacy). These obstacles can affect the optimal size of firms, and hence the
dispersion of their marginal products, and can affect different firms heterogeneously
and act as wedges that prevent firms from growing to their optimal size.7
Finally, we make use of a set of instruments for the first stage of the IV
regressions. These include (i) a set of five dummies for the size of the city where
the firm operates (each dummy takes the value of 1 for a particular population size
range), (ii) the percentage of foreign ownership of the firm, and (iii) the percentage
of sales of the firm going to foreign markets. We also experimented with other
potential instruments including firm age, legal status of the firm, and percentage of
capital held by the main owner of the firm, among others. However, none of these
appeared to be significant in the first stage. We will explain below the instruments
used for each of the public and private credit binary variables.
Figure 1 shows the percentage of firms in each economy that declare that
finance is an obstacle. The economies where firms most commonly declare financial
access problems are mainly African economies with a lower level of financial
development, followed by mainly Latin American economies. In economies like
the PRC and India, the share declaring financial access problems is much lower,
which is generally also true for all other Asian economies in the sample with the
exception of Bangladesh and Nepal. Figure 2 shows the shares of firms in each
economy that receive a credit line from either public or private institutions. The
sum of PUBi and PRIVi does not cover all firms in the sample since a sizable
proportion of them do not have a credit line. The PRC, India, the Lao People’s
Democratic Republic, and Viet Nam are the economies with the largest shares of
firms with access to public credit lines. In general, Asian economies tend to have
7See Le´on–Ledesma (2016) for a detailed analysis of the role of these obstacles in driving misallocation.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 131
Figure 1. Percentage of Firms Declaring Finance is an Obstacle to Operations
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
PRC = People’s Republic of China.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from World Bank. Enterprise Surveys and Indicator Surveys Sampling
Methodology. www.enterprisesurveys.org
Figure 2. Percentage of Firms Receiving Loan from Public Institutions
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
PRC = People’s Republic of China.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from World Bank. Enterprise Surveys and Indicator Surveys Sampling
Methodology. www.enterprisesurveys.org
132 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
a larger proportion of firms with access to public credit, which is consistent with
the presence of directed credit institutions. Outside this group, economies such as
Brazil, Egypt, and Russian Federation have a large proportion of firms with access
to public credit as well, which is (again) consistent with the existence of state-owned
lenders in the market.
Table 2 shows the distribution of public credit by firm size in each economy.8
On average, it appears that public credit is slightly biased toward medium and large
firms, and against small firms, when compared to the distribution of all firms in
Table 1. This varies substantially by economy, but it is evident for large economies
with an important element of public lending such as the PRC, India, and Russian
Federation. For economies with a low prevalence of public credit lines, all public
credit appears concentrated in a single size category.
Table 3 shows how the three possible credit outcomes (public, private, or no
credit) are distributed in each economy for firms that face financial obstacles and
those that do not. It is quite striking that, on average, the proportions are almost the
same for both categories of firms. Neither public nor private credit appears to be
more prevalent for firms that do not face financial obstacles. Of course, this result
compounds demand and supply effects, so we cannot extract meaningful structural
interpretations. Interestingly, this appears to be the case for most economies in the
sample.
V. Results
We now proceed to analyze the regression results. The dependent variables
measuring distortions were calculated in equations (7) and (8) and then logged. To
calculate αs, we averaged the capital share for firms by economy and sector, and
trimmed the upper and lower 5% to smooth out the effect of outliers. Unfortunately,
we only know a firm’s sector at a high level of aggregation; there are a total of
15 sectors for both industry and services, with agricultural firms being excluded.
Although it would be desirable to obtain capital shares for a larger number of sectors
to obtain measures of misallocation, this will not affect the regression results as we
include sector dummies that capture sector fixed effects. We then obtain the standard
deviation of the two distortions for each sector and average them by economy. The
average results for all economies are displayed in Table 4. The results show a high
level of dispersion for both measures. Consistent with other studies—such as Hsieh
and Klenow (2009) and Ha, Kiyota, and Yamanouchi (2016)—the factor market
distortion is larger than the size distortion. There is also wide variability between
economies. Angola displays the lowest size distortion and the Philippines displays
the largest. For factor market distortions, South Africa displays the lowest and Sri
Lanka displays the largest dispersions.
8There are only 39 economies out of the 45-economy sample for which public credit information is available.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 133
Table 2. Size Distribution of Firms Receiving Public Credit
Size Distribution by Number of Employees
Small (<20) Medium (20–100) Large (>100)
阿根廷
Bangladesh
玻利维亚
巴西
Bulgaria
智利
PRC
哥伦比亚
Costa Rica
Croatia
厄瓜多尔
埃及
El Salvador
加纳
危地马拉
Honduras
印度
印度尼西亚
伊拉克
肯尼亚
Lao PDR
马里
墨西哥
Mozambique
Nepal
秘鲁
菲律宾
Russian Federation
南非
斯里兰卡
瑞典
坦桑尼亚
Tunisia
Turkey
Ukraine
Uruguay
Viet Nam
赞比亚
Zimbabwe
全部的
Lao PDR = Lao People’s Democratic Republic, PRC = People’s Republic of China.
来源: Authors’ compilation.
44%
40%
0%
44%
60%
32%
35%
63%
58%
26%
100%
39%
20%
37%
50%
0%
49%
29%
20%
38%
38%
100%
29%
100%
45%
0%
67%
42%
0%
21%
33%
27%
43%
60%
33%
46%
38%
43%
33%
44%
16%
23%
100%
37%
20%
42%
4%
25%
35%
26%
0%
29%
60%
32%
50%
100%
23%
35%
70%
13%
38%
0%
64%
0%
45%
100%
33%
18%
0%
46%
50%
45%
20%
25%
33%
42%
12%
29%
33%
23%
41%
36%
0%
19%
20%
26%
61%
13%
6%
48%
0%
32%
20%
32%
0%
0%
28%
36%
10%
50%
24%
0%
7%
0%
9%
0%
0%
40%
100%
33%
17%
27%
37%
15%
33%
13%
50%
29%
33%
33%
The results of the regression analysis are presented in Tables 5 和 6 for τk
and τy, 分别. We use as controls the economy and sector dummies, 也
a set of other binary obstacle variables that were explained in the previous section.
The tables present the results with and without interaction terms for the OLS and
IV regressions.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
134 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
桌子 3. Allocation of Public and Private Loans by Financial Obstacles
If credit is an obstacle, 做
you have. . .?
If credit is not an obstacle,
do you have. . .?
Private
Credit
民众
Credit
不
Credit
Private
Credit
民众
Credit
不
Credit
Angola
阿根廷
Bangladesh
玻利维亚
巴西
Bulgaria
智利
PRC
哥伦比亚
Costa Rica
Croatia
厄瓜多尔
埃及
El Salvador
加纳
危地马拉
Honduras
印度
印度尼西亚
伊拉克
约旦
肯尼亚
Lao PDR
马里
墨西哥
Mozambique
Nepal
Nicaragua
秘鲁
菲律宾
Russian Federation
塞内加尔
南非
斯里兰卡
瑞典
坦桑尼亚
Tunisia
Turkey
乌干达
Ukraine
Uruguay
Viet Nam
赞比亚
Zimbabwe
全部的
Lao PDR = Lao People’s Democratic Republic, PRC = People’s Republic of China.
来源: Authors’ compilation.
96%
43%
52%
47%
36%
54%
23%
36%
26%
37%
14%
36%
86%
36%
83%
50%
52%
61%
66%
95%
81%
52%
60%
97%
54%
92%
46%
69%
26%
47%
65%
87%
78%
58%
67%
76%
40%
18%
87%
85%
47%
40%
83%
81%
62%
0%
56%
37%
55%
44%
41%
77%
5%
78%
27%
57%
56%
6%
68%
9%
46%
51%
4%
19%
2%
30%
43%
3%
7%
51%
8%
31%
37%
87%
37%
20%
10%
34%
32%
27%
19%
44%
55%
20%
20%
35%
31%
13%
9%
27%
0%
11%
14%
0%
23%
0%
3%
58%
2%
39%
17%
0%
8%
5%
6%
2%
0%
35%
17%
2%
0%
4%
25%
1%
2%
1%
15%
0%
1%
2%
12%
0%
0%
11%
0%
5%
15%
12%
0%
0%
21%
30%
2%
1%
12%
4%
46%
35%
53%
42%
46%
74%
7%
72%
24%
69%
64%
6%
59%
11%
48%
48%
4%
17%
3%
19%
43%
15%
2%
44%
7%
39%
31%
72%
51%
23%
13%
22%
31%
33%
18%
45%
69%
13%
15%
33%
30%
15%
18%
26%
0%
12%
8%
1%
26%
2%
3%
25%
1%
33%
12%
1%
3%
1%
11%
2%
1%
28%
13%
2%
0%
4%
6%
2%
1%
0%
3%
0%
0%
1%
11%
0%
1%
10%
3%
4%
11%
11%
0%
2%
13%
38%
3%
1%
13%
100%
32%
55%
44%
30%
57%
19%
71%
21%
40%
31%
44%
91%
32%
80%
52%
47%
68%
68%
95%
70%
54%
91%
91%
48%
92%
67%
63%
13%
61%
69%
90%
65%
58%
70%
77%
45%
34%
80%
78%
52%
32%
85%
90%
60%
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 135
桌子 4. Misallocation Measures: Dispersion of Distortions
Variable
StDev(τ _y)
StDev(τ _k)
意思是
Standard Deviation
最小
0.902
1.252
0.184
0.190
0.478
0.843
Max
1.255
1.604
来源: 作者的计算.
The instruments used for the first-stage probit for the public credit variable
如下面所述. 第一的, a set of dummies is created for the city in which the firm
is located, taking the value of 1 for a particular city size and zero otherwise. 这
sizes are “capital city,” “more than 1 百万,” “between 250,000 和 1 百万,”
“between 50,000 and 250,000,” and “less than 50,000.” The second instrument used
is a variable measuring the percentage of foreign ownership in the firm. 最后,
we use the rest of the control variables included in the regression. The set of city
dummies are undoubtedly exogenous and unlikely to be correlated with determinants
of distortions other than access to infrastructure, which we control for. 我们会
also expect foreign ownership to reduce access to public credit as local firms are
normally given preferential treatment.
For the first-stage probit for the private credit variable, we use the same
city-size dummies plus a variable measuring the percentage of sales going to
international markets (exports). It is likely that firms located closer to financial
centers and with more diversified and/or larger markets (exporters) will have better
access to private credit. Our first-stage probits, which are available upon request,
show that all the instruments are significant, the sign of their coefficients are as
预期的, and the regression is well behaved in general. 我们还尝试过
a wider set of instruments, but their correlation with the endogenous variables proved
to be too weak to identify a causal effect.
The results in Table 5 show that several variables are significant drivers of
the factor market distortion τk. This is especially the case for our finance-related
变量. The first result is that financial obstacles appear to increase the relative
cost of capital by close to 18% in all specifications as expected. This is also a very
significant effect. In the OLS regressions, access to both private and public loans
appears to significantly reduce the distortion. The interaction term appears to be
insignificant for private credit but significant for public credit. The negative effect
of public credit on the distortion appears to be stronger for firms that face financial
obstacles than for those that do not. 然而, as seen in Table 3, the distribution of
public credit does not appear to change significantly between these two types of firms.
所以, the total effect on the distribution of the distortion can only be inferred
from the Fields (2003) 分解. The IV regressions, 然而, tell a slightly
different story. The interpretation of the public and private loan variables cannot be
done the same way since the variables are now continuous. In the specification with
no interactions, having access to a private credit line reduces the distortion, 尽管
the effect of the public credit variable is not significant. The interaction variables
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
136 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
桌子 5. Regression Results for Factor Market Distortions (τ _k)
OLS Regressions
IV Regressions
Access to finance
Private loan (yes = 1)
Public loan (yes = 1)
Access to finance × Private loan
Access to finance × Public loan
Electricity
Transportation
Customs and trade regulations
Informal sector
Access to land
犯罪, theft
Tax rates
Tax administration
Business licensing
Political instability
腐败
法院
Labor regulations
Inadequate education workers
Country dummies
Sector dummies
持续的
(1)
0.184∗
(7.36)
−0.120∗
(−4.30)
−0.113∗
(−3.66)
−0.0335
(−1.40)
−0.0231
(−0.82)
−0.0982∗∗
(−2.97)
0.0679∗∗
(2.69)
0.00510
(0.17)
−0.0367
(−1.18)
−0.0465
(−1.85)
0.0525
(1.77)
−0.0326
(−1.06)
0.0176
(0.59)
−0.0371
(−1.44)
0.0808∗∗∗
(2.45)
0.0178
(0.54)
0.0328
(1.12)
YES
YES
−0.539∗∗∗
(−2.03)
(2)
0.206∗
(6.68)
−0.125∗
(−3.97)
−0.0693∗∗∗
(−2.11)
0.00938
(0.18)
−0.200∗∗
(−2.70)
−0.0334
(−1.40)
−0.0231
(−0.82)
−0.0972∗∗
(−2.94)
0.0675∗∗
(2.68)
0.00663
(0.22)
−0.0372
(−1.19)
−0.0468
(−1.86)
0.0530
(1.78)
−0.0327
(−1.06)
0.0183
(0.61)
−0.0380
(−1.47)
0.0810∗∗∗
(2.45)
0.0181
(0.55)
0.0321
(1.10)
YES
YES
−0.547∗∗∗
(−2.05)
(3)
0.175∗
(6.27)
−2.418∗
(−4.51)
0.497
(1.82)
−0.0186
(−0.71)
0.00365
(0.11)
0.0131
(0.29)
0.0364
(1.32)
−0.0754∗∗∗
(−2.17)
−0.0622
(−1.77)
−0.0659∗∗∗
(−2.25)
0.0805∗∗∗
(2.35)
−0.0927∗∗∗
(−2.50)
−0.0190
(−0.59)
−0.0184
(−0.60)
0.0875∗∗∗
(2.31)
0.105∗∗
(2.79)
0.110∗∗
(3.10)
YES
YES
0.0451
(0.24)
14,828
0.013
(4)
0.175∗∗
(3.13)
−2.540∗
(−4.71)
0.608∗∗∗
(2.20)
0.234∗∗∗
(2.00)
−0.415∗∗∗
(−2.16)
−0.0186
(−0.72)
0.00375
(0.11)
0.0158
(0.35)
0.0359
(1.30)
−0.0665
(−1.91)
−0.0641
(−1.82)
−0.0670∗∗∗
(−2.29)
0.0830∗∗∗
(2.42)
−0.0917∗∗∗
(−2.47)
−0.0175
(−0.54)
−0.0186
(−0.61)
0.0826∗∗∗
(2.18)
0.104∗∗
(2.75)
0.108∗∗
(3.04)
YES
YES
0.0577
(0.31)
14,828
0.014
18,025
0.014
氮
R∧2
IV = instrumental variable, OLS = ordinary least squares.
Notes: ∗∗∗ = 10% level of significance, ∗∗ = 5% level of significance, ∗ = 1% level of significance. t statistics
in parentheses. Heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors. See text for the IV procedure implemented using a
first-stage probit for public and private credit.
来源: 作者的计算.
18,025
0.015
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 137
桌子 6. Regression Results for Factor Market Distortions (τ _y)
OLS Regressions
IV Regressions
Access to finance
Private loan (yes = 1)
Public loan (yes = 1)
Access to finance × Private loan
Access to finance × Public loan
Electricity
Transportation
Customs and trade regulations
Informal sector
Access to land
犯罪, theft
Tax rates
Tax administration
Business licensing
Political instability
腐败
法院
Labor regulations
Inadequate education workers
Country dummies
Sector dummies
持续的
(1)
0.133∗
(7.27)
−0.083∗
(−3.97)
−0.0728∗∗
(−3.11)
−0.0220
(−1.25)
−0.00757
(−0.37)
−0.0716∗∗
(−2.87)
0.0453∗∗∗
(2.50)
0.00463
(0.21)
−0.0325
(−1.40)
−0.0221
(−1.17)
0.0346
(1.55)
−0.0293
(−1.27)
0.00970
(0.42)
−0.0362
(−1.89)
0.0694∗∗
(2.86)
0.0125
(0.51)
0.0264
(1.21)
YES
YES
−0.379∗∗∗
(−2.20)
(2)
0.146∗
(6.58)
−0.086∗
(−3.70)
−0.0455
(−1.85)
0.00946
(0.25)
−0.126∗∗∗
(−2.18)
−0.0220
(−1.25)
−0.00755
(−0.37)
−0.0710∗∗
(−2.85)
0.0451∗∗∗
(2.49)
0.00567
(0.26)
−0.0328
(−1.42)
−0.0223
(−1.17)
0.0349
(1.57)
−0.0293
(−1.27)
0.0101
(0.44)
−0.0367
(−1.92)
0.0695∗∗
(2.86)
0.0126
(0.52)
0.0259
(1.19)
YES
YES
−0.383∗∗∗
(−2.22)
(3)
0.125∗
(6.08)
−1.720∗
(−4.35)
0.326
(1.63)
−0.0128
(−0.67)
0.0186
(0.75)
0.00625
(0.19)
0.0224
(1.11)
−0.0537∗∗∗
(−2.10)
−0.0530∗∗∗
(−2.04)
−0.0376
(−1.75)
0.0520∗∗∗
(2.06)
−0.0737∗∗
(−2.70)
−0.0188
(−0.79)
−0.0192
(−0.86)
0.0739∗∗
(2.65)
0.0728∗∗
(2.63)
0.0784∗∗
(3.01)
YES
YES
−0.05
(−0.39)
(4)
0.104∗∗∗
(2.51)
−1.802∗
(−4.54)
0.367
(1.80)
0.166
(1.93)
−0.152
(−1.07)
−0.0129
(−0.67)
0.0188
(0.76)
0.00707
(0.21)
0.0224
(1.11)
−0.0480
(−1.87)
−0.0538∗∗∗
(−2.08)
−0.0384
(−1.78)
0.0531∗∗∗
(2.10)
−0.0728∗∗
(−2.67)
−0.0185
(−0.78)
−0.0187
(−0.83)
0.0707∗∗∗
(2.54)
0.0718∗∗
(2.59)
0.0773∗∗
(2.96)
YES
YES
−0.04
(−0.30)
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
18,027
0.02
氮
R∧2
IV = instrumental variable, OLS = ordinary least squares.
Notes: ∗∗∗ = 10% level of significance, ∗∗ = 5% level of significance, ∗ = 1% level of significance. t statistics
in parentheses. Heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors. See text for the IV procedure implemented using a
first-stage probit for public and private credit.
来源: 作者的计算.
14,828
0.02
18,027
0.02
14,828
0.02
138 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
in column (4) show that public credit now reduces the distortion for firms that face
financial obstacles. The total effect for these firms is, 然而, still negative. 为了
private loans, the effect is the opposite; it reduces the distortion more for firms
that do not report financial obstacles. 全面的, the regression is jointly significant.
然而, the variables explain only a small part of the variation of the endogenous
variable as shown by the R∧2 coefficient.
For the size distortion, the results are presented in Table 6. Lack of access to
finance acts as a size subsidy in the sense that it increases the cost share of labor
in value added. 这, 然而, may well be the consequence of a lack of access to
finance leading to higher labor intensity due to a lack of access to capital. Public and
private credit have the opposite effects as were expected from the OLS regressions.
The significant result for the public credit variable disappears when we introduce
the interaction with financial access in the IV regressions. 然而, in the OLS
regression, access to a public loan for firms that face financial difficulties has a
significantly negative effect; it acts as a size tax. Turning to the IV regressions, 这
only variable that appears to be significant is access to private credit, which reduces
the cost share of labor. Public credit has a positive effect, but it is not significantly
different from zero. The interaction terms are not significant either. 因此, 存在
the recipient of a public or a private loan when the firm faces financial obstacles
does not appear to be significantly different from when they do not face financial
obstacles. 全面的, the results are not very conclusive beyond the fact that obstacles
to finance and accessing a private loan are significant drivers of size distortions.
最后, we turn to the Fields (2003) decompositions for both distortions in
Tables 7 和 8. The results show the percentage of the explained part of the dispersion
of distortions to which each variable contributes. This contribution can be positive
if the variable increases the dispersion of the distortion, or negative if it reduces it.
These results should be seen in conjunction with the regression results to analyze
whether these effects are significant. The sum of the contributions of the variables,
including economy and sector dummies, 是 100 as we are looking at the explained
部分. We focus here on the IV regression results in columns (3) 和 (4), although we
also present the results from the OLS regressions.
For the factor market distortion, all obstacles explain almost half of the
dispersion of the distortion, the other half is explained mainly by economy dummies.
Of the obstacles, the main driver is access to finance. Financial obstacles increase
the dispersion of τk, leading to misallocation. Being the recipient of a public loan has
a small positive effect on dispersion as well. For firms facing financial obstacles, 这
effect is negative. 然而, the magnitude of the effect is very small in comparison
with not having a loan. For private loans, the effect is positive. The effect of having a
private loan for firms that face financial obstacles is positive and sizable. Private loans
appear to increase the dispersion of the distortion, thus their allocation across firms
increases allocative inefficiency. This is indicative of possible distortions in private
credit markets. Public credit, which is designed to allow firms with viable investment
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 139
桌子 7. Contribution of Variables to the Explained Dispersion of τ _k (%)
OLS Regressions
IV Regressions
(1)
24.36
7.45
3.55
Access to finance
Private loan (yes = 1)
Public loan (yes = 1)
Access to finance × Private loan
Access to finance × Public loan
Electricity
Transportation
Customs and trade regulations
Informal sector
Access to land
犯罪, theft
Tax rates
Tax administration
Business licensing
Political instability
腐败
法院
Labor regulations
Inadequate education workers
All obstacles
Country dummies
Sector dummies
全部的
IV = instrumental variable, OLS = ordinary least squares.
来源: 作者的计算.
0.48
0.13
3.40
4.00
0.10
0.15
0.98
0.89
0.19
−0.35
0.40
2.55
0.29
0.73
49.29
48.17
2.54
100
(2)
26.35
7.47
2.11
0.20
1.59
0.46
0.12
3.26
3.85
0.12
0.15
0.95
0.87
0.18
−0.35
0.39
2.47
0.28
0.70
51.19
46.41
2.40
100
(3)
21.68
7.97
0.20
0.23
−0.04
−0.51
1.73
−0.12
0.62
1.80
0.81
1.51
0.47
0.36
3.70
2.07
2.25
44.74
55.50
−0.24
100
(4)
20.37
7.86
0.23
8.89
−3.70
0.22
−0.04
−0.57
1.60
−0.10
0.60
1.72
0.79
1.40
0.40
0.34
3.28
1.92
2.07
47.26
53.14
−0.41
100
projects to bypass financial constraints, only reduces the allocative inefficiency of
factors of production by a small amount for all firms. It even increases it marginally
for firms that do not report facing financial obstacles. 全面的, 然而, 的作用
public credit in improving aggregate TFP through improved allocation of capital
and labor is almost negligible.
A very similar picture arises from the decomposition of τy. 在这种情况下, 使用权
to finance has a smaller effect, and it is being a recipient of a private loan that seems
to dominate by increasing substantially the dispersion of the size distortion. 民众
credit also increases this dispersion, except for firms that face financial obstacles.
然而, the effect of these interaction variables and the direct effect of public credit
is not significant when we look at the regression results. 实际上, not having a credit
line at all while facing financial obstacles appears to lead to a smaller dispersion of
distortions than having a credit line.
Distortions that affect firms in an idiosyncratic way lead to an inefficient
allocation of capital and labor, and firm sizes. These distortions, whether generated
by market or government failures, may be caused by an inefficient allocation of
credit. Our evidence shows that the allocation of both private and public credit
leads to an increase in the dispersion of distortions. Public credit only reduces
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
140 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
桌子 8. Contribution of Variables to the Explained Dispersion of τ _y (%)
OLS Regressions
IV Regressions
(1)
17.71
5.79
1.71
Access to finance
Private loan (yes = 1)
Public loan (yes = 1)
Access to finance × Private loan
Access to finance × Public loan
Electricity
Transportation
Customs and trade regulations
Informal sector
Access to land
犯罪, theft
Tax rates
Tax administration
Business licensing
Political instability
腐败
法院
Labor regulations
Inadequate education workers
All obstacles
Country dummies
Sector dummies
全部的
IV = instrumental variable, OLS = ordinary least squares.
来源: 作者的计算.
0.46
0.02
2.65
2.40
0.08
0.34
0.44
0.51
0.33
−0.41
0.84
2.28
0.20
0.48
35.82
61.27
2.91
100
(2)
19.03
5.93
1.05
0.19
0.79
0.45
0.02
2.58
2.34
0.10
0.33
0.43
0.51
0.32
−0.42
0.84
2.24
0.20
0.47
37.38
59.83
2.80
(3)
15.17
24.96
1.27
0.21
−0.15
−0.29
0.82
0.29
1.09
1.15
0.09
2.17
0.96
0.61
3.13
1.13
0.75
53.36
45.22
1.42
(4)
12.25
25.44
1.39
5.81
−1.64
0.21
−0.15
−0.32
0.80
0.25
1.07
1.14
0.09
2.08
0.92
0.58
2.92
1.08
0.72
54.63
44.09
1.27
100
100
100
this dispersion for firms that face (self-declared) financial obstacles. 很明显,
public credit does not appear to compensate for the distortions that exist in private
credit markets. 然而, the bulk of the dispersion of these distortions remains
unexplained. Finance appears to be important only when we look at the part of the
distortions that we are able to explain with observations. In that sense, our results are
consistent with several results in the literature that attribute a minor role to financial
access in explaining misallocation.
六、. 结论
Misallocation implies that, with the same amount of capital, 劳动, 和
firm-level TFP, aggregate TFP can be higher if factors of production were reallocated
between firms. Distortions that affect firms in a heterogeneous way lead to
suboptimal capital–labor ratios at the firm level and a distribution of firm sizes
that is not consistent with the distribution of their TFP. One of the factors that may
drive these distortions are financial frictions that prevent viable projects from being
financed and allow unviable projects to be financed.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 141
We have studied quantitatively the effect of access to finance to explain the
dispersion of factor market and size distortions that drive misallocation. Our focus
is not only on the effect of financial obstacles, but also on whether public credit
has a significant effect in improving allocation. Directed credit policies through
government-owned institutions are very common in many emerging markets and
have gained importance in recent decades. 因此, it is important to understand
whether government credit has any positive effect on aggregate TFP, and hence per
capita income, through an improved allocation of resources.
We use a database of close to 23,000 firms in 45 economies and derive
two measures of distortions from the Hsieh and Klenow (2009) 模型. 第一个
measures factor market distortions that prevent firms from achieving their optimal
capital–labor ratio. The second measures size distortions that prevent firms from
achieving their optimal size as dictated by their TFP. We then use a regression
approach to measure the effect of self-declared access-to-finance obstacles, 使用权
to a government-owned bank credit line, and access to a private-owned bank credit
line on these two measures of distortions. We instrumentalize the public and private
credit line variables to isolate their treatment effect. We then use a regression-based
decomposition that allows us to see whether these variables increase or decrease the
dispersion of distortions across firms.
Our results show that access-to-finance obstacles increase the dispersion
of both factor market distortions and size distortions. Private credit increases
the dispersion of both distortions, especially the size distortion. 这不是
surprising given that it is the existence of informational asymmetries together with
underdeveloped financial markets that can lead to an inefficient allocation of private
credit. Public credit, 另一方面, has a very small effect. For firms that do
not face financial obstacles, it increases slightly the dispersion of both distortions.
For firms that face financial obstacles, it decreases slightly the dispersion, 但它
is not significant in the case of size distortions. 然而, public credit does not
appear to compensate for the distortions that exist in the private credit markets.
We thus conclude that public credit does not appear to improve significantly the
informational and regulatory frictions that exist in credit markets even among our
sample that is dominated by developing economies with lower levels of financial
深度. The majority of the dispersion of these distortions remains unexplained.
Financial variables appear only to be important in driving the explained part of these
distortions and are significant. 然而, they cannot explain a sizable enough part
of them to be considered as the key drivers of misallocation.
参考
Angrist, J. D ., and J.-S. Pischke. 2009. Mostly Harmless Econometrics. 普林斯顿大学出版社.
Antunes, A。, 时间. Cavalcanti, 和一个. Villamil. 2015. The Effects of Credit Subsidies on Development.
Economic Theory 58 (1): 1–30.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
142 ASIAN DEVELOPMENT REVIEW
Banerjee, A。, and E. Duflo. 2005. Growth Theory Through the Lens of Development Economics.
Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume 1A. North-Holland.
——. 2014. Do Firms Want to Borrow More? Testing Credit Constraints Using a Directed Lending
程序. Review of Economic Studies 81 (2): 572–607.
Banerjee, A。, 和乙. Moll. 2010. Why Does Misallocation Persist? American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics 2 (1): 189–206.
Bartelsman, E., J. Haltiwanger, 和S. Scarpetta. 2013. Cross-Country Differences in Productivity:
The Role of Allocation and Selection. American Economic Review 103 (1): 305–34.
Buera, F。, J. Kaboski, 和 Y. Shin. 2011. Finance and Development: A Tale of Two Sectors.
American Economic Review 101 (5): 1964–2002.
Carvalho, D. 2014. The Real Effects of Government-Owned Banks. Journal of Finance 69 (2):
577–609.
Eslava, M。, A. Maffioli, 和M. Mel´endez. 2014. Credit Constraints and Business Performance:
Evidence from Public Lending in Colombia. Documentos CEDE 37. Bogota: Universidad
de Los Andes.
Fields, G. S. 2003. Accounting for Income Inequality and Its Change: A New Method with
Application to the Distribution of Earnings in the United States. Research in Labor
经济学 22 (2003): 1–38.
Guner, N。, G. Ventura, 和 Y. 徐. 2008. Macroeconomic Implications of Size-Dependent Policies.
Review of Economic Dynamics 11 (4): 721–44.
Ha, D. 时间. T。, K. Kiyota, and K. Yamanouchi. 2016. Misallocation and Productivity: The Case of
Vietnamese Manufacturing. Asian Development Review. 33 (2): 94–118.
Hopenhayn, H. 1992. Entry, 出口, and Firm Dynamics in Long Run Equilibrium. Econometrica
60 (5): 1127–50.
Hopenhayn, H。, 和R. Rogerson. 1993. Job Turnover and Policy Evaluation: A General
Equilibrium Analysis. Journal of Political Economy 101 (5): 915–38.
Hsieh, C。, 和P. Klenow. 2009. Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4): 1403–48.
Kalemli–Ozcan, S。, 和乙. Sorensen. 2012. Misallocation, Property Rights, and Access to Finance:
Evidence from within and across Africa. NBER Working Paper 18030. 剑桥, 嘛:
National Bureau for Economic Research.
Kiyotaki, N。, 和 J. 摩尔. 1997. Credit Cycles. Journal of Political Economy 105 (2): 211–48.
La Porta, R。, F. Lopez de Silanes, 和一个. Shleifer. 2002. Government Ownership of Banks. 杂志
of Finance 62 (1): 265–302.
Le´on–Ledesma, 中号. A. 2016. Potential Growth, Misallocation, and Institutional Obstacles:
Firm-Level Evidence. ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 480. Manila: Asian
Development Bank.
Le´on–Ledesma, 中号. A。, 磷. McAdam, 和一个. Willman. 2010. Identifying the Elasticity of
Substitution with Biased Technical Change. American Economic Review 100 (4): 1330–57.
——. 2015. Production Technology Estimates and Balanced Growth. Oxford Bulletin of Economics
和统计 77 (1): 40–65.
Midrigan, 五、, 和D. 是. 徐. 2014. Finance and Misallocation: Evidence from Plant-Level Data.
American Economic Review 104 (2): 422–58.
Moll, 乙. 2014. Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-Financing Undo Capital
Misallocation? American Economic Review 104 (10): 3186–221.
Restuccia, D ., 和R. Rogerson. 2008. Policy Distortions and Aggregate Productivity with
Heterogenous Establishments. Review of Economic Dynamics 11 (4): 707–20.
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
.
/
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
MISALLOCATION, ACCESS TO FINANCE, AND PUBLIC CREDIT 143
Ribeiro, 乙. P。, 和 J. A. de Negri. 2009. Estimating the Causal Effect of Access to Public Credit
on Productivity: The Case of Brazil. Unpublished.
Shorrocks, A. F. 1982. Inequality Decomposition by Factor Components. Econometrica 50 (1):
193–211.
Udry, C. 2011. Misallocation, 生长, and Financial Market Imperfections. 新天堂: 耶鲁大学
大学.
Wooldridge, J. 中号. 2010. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, Second Edition.
与新闻界.
World Bank. Enterprise Surveys and Indicator Surveys Sampling Methodology. 万维网
.enterprisesurveys.org
我
D
哦
w
n
哦
A
d
e
d
F
r
哦
米
H
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
我
r
e
C
t
.
米
我
t
.
/
e
d
你
A
d
e
v
/
A
r
t
我
C
e
–
p
d
我
F
/
/
/
/
3
3
2
1
1
9
1
6
4
3
2
7
0
A
d
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
0
7
5
p
d
/
.
F
乙
y
G
你
e
s
t
t
哦
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
米
乙
e
r
2
0
2
3
下载pdf