Improving the Lot of the Farmer
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
Improving the Lot of the Farmer:
Development Challenges in Timor-
Leste during the Second Decade of
Independence*
Mats Lundahl
Stockholm School of
Economics
Box 6501, SE-113 83
Stockholm, Sweden
Mats.Lundahl@hhs.se
Fredrik Sjöholm
Lund University and Research
Institute of Industrial
Economics
Box 7082, SE-220 07 Lund,
Sweden
Fredrik.Sjoholm@nek.lu.se
Abstrait
Large segments of the rural Timorese population survive on sub-
sistence farming characterized by simple production methods and
low output. Broad-based improvements in Timorese living stan-
dards require increased agricultural output. This article discusses
what determines agricultural development in Timor-Leste and
how such development can be achieved. The main causes of low
agricultural output are found to be scarcity of land and capital,
poor technology and education, and lack of government support,
such as extension services and provision of infrastructure. Nous
construct a model of an agricultural household to examine how
increased market incentives will affect agricultural output and in-
comes. The effects of different price changes on household pro-
duction, consommation, sales, revenu, and leisure are investigated.
We find that the objective of increasing the living standard of
Timorese farmers may in part be achieved via increased earning
opportunities outside agriculture.
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
1. Introduction
Dans 2012, Timor-Leste celebrated its tenth anniversary as an
independent nation. Economically and socially, things
have not turned out quite as envisaged at the dawn of in-
dependence. It is clear that the country has a long way to
go before poverty will be eradicated. Disappointment with
* The article was presented at the Asian Economic Panel meeting
in Lund, 10–11 September 2012. We are grateful for constructive
comments to Machiko Nisanke, Tobias Axelsson, Anne Booth,
Arne Bigsten, and Naoyuki Yoshino. Financial support from
the Ragnar Söderberg foundation is gratefully acknowledged.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Asian Economic Papers 12:2
© 2013 The Earth Institute at Columbia University and the Massachusetts
Institut de technologie
est ce que je:10.1162/ASEP_a_00211
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
the lack of development constitutes a source of political turbulence, most vividly
demonstrated by the violence between different groups in 2006 and by the murder
attempt on President José Ramos Horta in 2008.
To be fair, the expectations were hardly realistic. The Indonesians left behind a coun-
try with an essentially destroyed infrastructure, a country that was far poorer than it
should have been. It is estimated that real GDP fell by one-third between 1998 et
1999 as a result of the violence and turmoil that accompanied the withdrawal
(UNDP 2002, 57–58).
Another way of measuring the extent of destruction is by looking directly at the so-
cial and physical infrastructure. Regardless of which indicator we choose, the result
is dismal (UNDP 2002). En moyenne, peasant families lost 58 percent of their goats,
48 percent of their cattle, et 47 percent of their pigs (c'est à dire., half their livestock was
gone). All existing banks, including the regional branch ofªce of the central bank,
were either looted or destroyed and, as a result, all transactions in the economy had
to be carried out on a cash or barter basis. One-third of the electricity-generating ca-
pacity in the capital was lost, and in the provinces the district capitals lost between
50 et 90 pour cent. The social infrastructure was more or less wiped out. No less
que 80 percent of all schools and medical clinics were destroyed. The transport and
communications network, including the markets, collapsed. Most of the ªxed tele-
phone lines were damaged and transportation was in extremely short supply.
Enfin, the entire public administration ceased to function. The civil service at the
time consisted of some 28,000 ofªcials. All the top-level ofªcials, about one-fourth,
were Indonesians who left East Timor (UNDP 2002).
Considering this turmoil, it should not come as a surprise that Timor-Leste is a very
poor country. Income per capita is only about 14 percent of that of developing East
Asia and the Paciªc, ou 41 percent of the incomes of developing sub-Saharan Africa
(World Bank 2012). Poverty to a large extent is a rural phenomenon. Entre 70 et
80 percent of the population is dependent on agriculture for its livelihood and three-
quarters of the poor live in rural areas (Lundahl and Sjöholm 2007; UNDP 2011).
Timor-Leste displays all the characteristics of a labor surplus economy as described
by in the classic work of Arthur Lewis (1954). Most people are employed in subsis-
tence farming where the marginal and average productivity of labor, and hence per
capita output, is low. Few people work in the modern sector. De plus, the situation
may rapidly be getting worse due to the extraordinarily high fertility rate—close to
8 children per woman of child-bearing age in the early years of independence and
presque 6 children per woman in recent years (Ministry of Health et al. 2004, 6;
UNDP 2011). This means that the population is growing rapidly and that each year
72
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
à propos 17,000 young Timorese enter the labor force. Par conséquent, unemployment and
underemployment rates seem to be increasing.
Heureusement, there are signs of positive development during the last ªve years:
Incomes have increased, and poverty seems to be declining from its high level.
These improvements have been achieved by strong increases in public expenditures
made possible by the oil revenues. Timor-Leste is often claimed to be the most oil-
dependent country in the world, and oil and gas revenues account for around
90 percent of state revenue. Oil revenues have been spent on funding the return of
autour 150,000 refugees to their villages, on pensions to war veterans, on cash
transfer programs to vulnerable households, and on various infrastructure projects
(UNDP 2011, 17). In this respect it is a blessing but it also leaves the country at the
risk of falling prey to the resource curse of low growth and social turbulence
(Lundahl and Sjöholm 2008a).
Long-term development is likely to require modern sector development. For the
foreseeable future, cependant, is it clear that the possibility of moving people out of
agriculture so as to increase average productivity and income is limited. The only
booming industry is oil production, which provides few jobs. There are no signs of
an emerging manufacturing industry. Lundahl and Sjöholm (2009un) make a back-of-
the-envelope calculation of the annual growth of output required in the modern sec-
tor just to keep the share of the labor force in agriculture constant: 21 percent if the
public sector is included and a staggering 106 percent if not. It should also be noted
that these ªgures are based on optimistic assumptions with regard to employment
elasticities (equal to 1) in the modern sector (the change in modern sector employ-
ment when the output of this sector increases). More conservative assumptions
make the required growth rates even higher.
The lack of a modern sector puts the poor rural population in a difªcult position
and leaves little room for per capita income growth other than through increased
agricultural output. Autrement dit, living standards will remain low for the rural
population unless there is a substantial increase in farm production. In the short
run, and until a modern sector begins to emerge, improvements in agriculture con-
stitute the only way of improving livelihoods in Timor-Leste.
In the present article we discuss what determines agricultural development in
Timor-Leste and how such development can be achieved. This is done in two steps.
The ªrst one takes the production function as its point of departure. Agricultural
output is seen as a function of inputs (atterrir, capital and labor) and technology,
which in turn are inºuenced by the infrastructure and institutions of the economy.
73
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
De plus, output is also affected by external factors that cannot be inºuenced by
policy measures. The second part emphasizes the fact that Timor-Leste is a market
economy. A model of an agricultural household is constructed. The static optimum
of the household is derived and the effects on production, consommation, sales, dans-
come, and leisure of the household of different price incentives (changes in food
prices, cash crop prices and prices of manufactured goods) are investigated.
2. The situation in agriculture
Large segments of the rural Timorese population survive on subsistence farming.
Farmers tend to use simple production methods to grow food crops for their own
consumption and the surplus sold in the market is small. Whatever cash incomes
that are generated are used to buy essential food, kerosene, salt (Barlow 2001, 110)
and also, de plus en plus, cheap Indonesian consumer goods (Conroy 2006, 21). The im-
portance of subsistence farming differs between regions, cependant. About 80 pour cent
of the rural households in the Eastern region are classiªed as subsistence farmers,
compared to a mere 11 percent in central Timor-Leste, et 32 percent in the Western
region (Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry, and Fisheries [MAFF] 2004, 2).
The main staple crops in Timor-Leste are rice and maize. Quelques 80 pour cent de la
households grow the former and slightly more than 20 percent the latter (UNDP
2006, 27; UNDP 2011, 79). Almost all maize and about 75 percent of the rice are for
own consumption; little agricultural produce is traded. De plus, the land area
used for maize is about three times as large as the land used for rice. The total area
used for rice is actually substantially smaller than the corresponding area around
1975 (a peak period). Rice and maize are supplemented by cassava, which is grown
by most rural households, often to be used as a reserve when the supply of rice and
maize has run out. The same is true for sweet potatoes and taro.
The poverty of the farming population is of course caused by low productivity in
agriculture. Cependant, there are some indications that productivity may be increas-
ing. Lundahl and Sjöholm (2007) compared agricultural productivity in Timor-Leste
with other countries in the region in 2005. Productivity was substantially lower in
Timor-Leste than in any other of the included Southeast Asian countries. Pour dans-
position, it was on average 250 percent higher in rice production in other countries
and about 310 percent higher in the production of maize. Chiffre 1 shows that pro-
ductivité, measured as physical output per hectare, for rice and maize remains low
dans 2010, but not as low as in 2005. The production of rice per hectare is approxi-
mately the same as in Cambodia and Thailand, much higher than in Papua New
Guinea, but substantially lower than in neighboring Indonesia. The progress in
maize is slower and productivity remains lower than in all other countries. C'est
74
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
Chiffre 1. Productivity in agriculture in 2010 in selected East Asian countries and Papua New
Guinea (tons per hectare)
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Source: FAO Statistics Division, available at http://faostat.fao.org/site/567/DesktopDefault.aspx?PageID 567. Accessed 30 Juillet 2012.
around half of that of Indonesia and even lower in comparison with two countries
at a similar development level—Laos and Papua New Guinea. It should also be
noted that the ªgures reported by the Food and Agricultural Organization (FAO)
might be exaggerated. Other sources claim that the production of maize is 1.16 tons
per hectare, 1.61 tons for rice, et 3.0 tons for the production of irrigated rice
(MAFF 2009).
Coffee is the main cash crop in Timor-Leste and it is also the country’s main export
bien. Production is concentrated to the highlands (Fox 2001, 164). Around 67,000
households grew coffee in 2009 (World Bank 2011a, 41). The quality of the Timorese
coffee is good or has high potential. So far, exports have predominantly targeted
high-quality niches in foreign markets. The decision by Starbucks to sell coffee from
Timor-Leste has provided a major boost to the reputation of the product and has
opened a large potential market.
The main problem with expanding coffee production is that little on-farm invest-
ment has been made. Due to poor husbandry of the coffee trees, crops are small, et
75
Asian Economic Papers
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
delivery is irregular. Par exemple, yields are reported to be a mere 150–200 kilos of
green beans per hectare (World Bank 2011a, 41). The irregularity and the small size
of the coffee crops is a major obstacle when it comes to attracting foreign purchasers
who require a high degree of predictability. Important improvements can also be
made in the processing of the coffee.
Maize and rice are the dominant staple crops and coffee dominates cash cropping,
but farmers in Timor-Leste grow a number of other crops as well. Fruit trees are
common, there has been some success with soy beans, and legumes are important
for conserving and increasing soil fertility. Farmers are often deliberately growing
different crops to reduce risks and spread harvests across the year. Most of them
also have animals, like chickens, goats, and cattle. Encore, production is almost ex-
clusively for subsistence.
3. Determinants of agricultural development
Chiffre 2 divides the factors affecting agricultural output into different categories.
D'abord, there are the external factors—that is, the factors that are beyond the control of
farmers or policymakers but that could have an impact on agricultural output. Tel
factors could for instance include climate and world market prices of agricultural
goods. Deuxième, agricultural production is affected by the amount of inputs used in
agriculture. Inputs include a range of factors, from labor and land to capital, comme
seeds, eau, fertilizer and tools. De plus, the better the technology, the more out-
put will be produced with a given bundle of inputs. In practice, it can be difªcult to
separate inputs and technology in agriculture. New seeds are inputs but their
proper use may require technological change (par exemple., through extension services) et
additional inputs (such as irrigation) être efficace, as in the case of the Green Rev-
olution. Enfin, investments in inputs and technology are affected by infrastructural
and institutional factors. These include for instance transportation, marchés, et
property (atterrir) droits.
3.1 External factors
Parts of Southeast Asia are among the most fertile areas on earth. Malheureusement,
Timor-Leste is not one of those places. The fertile part of Southeast Asia ends some-
where after Bali, and the eastern part of the archipelago is characterized by a climate
that is not ideal for agriculture. The problem is best described as one of too little or
too irregular rain and land with steep slopes and low fertility.
The climate in Timor-Leste is a typical monsoon climate with a wet season extend-
ing from around December to March and a dry season from around May to October,
but with local geographic variations. The annual rainfall ranges between 500 et
76
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
Chiffre 2. The determinants of agricultural output
Source: Authors’ calculations.
1,500 mm in the relatively dry north and over 2,000 mm in the relatively wet south.
Local variations in rainfall are common as Timor-Leste is surprisingly ecologically
diverse for being a relatively small country (Fox 2001, 155). The rainfall can be irreg-
ular. Par exemple, Dili sometimes receives 30 percent of its annual rainfall in a single
day (UNDP 2006, 19).
De plus, there are regular droughts in Timor-Leste. Such droughts occur approxi-
mately every fourth year. Then the rainfall is not only reduced by as much as 50 par-
cent but the drought also delays the wet season by two to three months, lequel
causes further difªculties for agriculture. Par exemple, the drought in 2002–03 re-
duced output by about 21 pour cent (UNDP 2006, 21) et en 2007, maize, rice, and cas-
sava production (in cereal equivalents) was reported to be 25–30 percent lower than
during the previous few years (FAO and World Food Programme 2007, 5).
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
Parts of the Southeast Asian archipelago are fertile because of a fortunate combina-
tion of large rivers and volcanic soil. Timor-Leste, cependant, has few rivers and, plus
importantly, the soil is not volcanic but instead consists of limestone and metamor-
phosed marine clays, a combination that is substantially less fertile (MAFF 2004, 1).
An additional problem is that the country is mountainous. Around half of the
land has a slope of 40 percent or more, which makes agricultural activities difªcult
to pursue.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
3.2 Land
The combination of Timor-Leste’s particular soil, the steep slope of the land, et le
irregular and heavy rainfall makes the land fragile and prone to erode. Natural ero-
sion rates are high, as is the rate of man-made deforestation. This is partly caused
by “slash-and-burn” cultivation, which is still common in the country. Even more
important is the effect of logging for ªrewood. The demand for ªrewood has
77
Asian Economic Papers
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
increased in recent years, partly as a consequence of the removal of kerosene subsi-
dies. The increased demand has put pressure on the forests and aggravated land
erosion, especially in areas close to towns and major villages. There are no recent
ªgures on soil erosion in Timor-Leste, but the forest loss from 1972–99 was esti-
mated at about 1.1 pour cent par an (UNDP 2006, 27), and the Ministry of Agricul-
ture, Forestry and Fisheries (2007, 19) reports the same ªgure for 2000–05.
The reduction of arable land because of erosion in combination with the high fertil-
ity rate means that little agricultural land is available in Timor-Leste, on average
only around 0.4 hectares per capita (UNDP 2006, Tableau 2.1). The median area is even
lower, 0.22 hectares per person and less than 5 percent of the landowning rural pop-
ulation have more than 1 hectare per person (Ministry of Planning and Finance and
World Bank 2003, 30). Most people, cependant, do have access to some land. Ainsi,
there are few landless people in Timor-Leste, in stark contrast to the situation in
many other countries in Southeast Asia. The share of irrigated land is only 22 par-
cent of the total (UNDP 2006, 26).
3.3 Capital
Two types of capital are of interest in the discussion of agricultural development.
The ªrst is physical capital such as machinery and the second is ªnancial capital,
mainly credit. The use of machinery in agriculture, for example tractors, is ex-
tremely limited in Timor-Leste, partly because of the inability of the poor farmer to
pay for fuel. Cultivation is characterized by production methods that have changed
little for several decades or perhaps even centuries.
Irrigation schemes are difªcult to implement in Timor-Leste. Rainfall is irregular
and most rivers are completely dry for large parts of the year. Even in those in-
stances where some type of irrigation exists, it tends to be simple and unreliable.
Irrigation systems are often crucially dependent on the water level in the rivers,
which has to reach the level of the intake of the irrigation system. There are few in-
stances where a pump can help farmers transferring water from its prime supply to
the irrigation systems. As an example on the low quality of irrigation, it was re-
ported that only a few hundred irrigation schemes existed in Timor-Leste around
the time of independence and only around 20 of these could store water (MAFF
2004, 4). Maintenance is a major problem and irrigation schemes are often ruined by
ºooding rivers.
The lack of irrigation is a major problem when it comes to expanding agricultural
output. The lack of water is particularly troublesome in the case of rice production.
Cependant, less than 20 percent of the irrigated land produces a second rice crop
78
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
(MAFF 2007). Autrement dit, agricultural output is low even when water is not the
binding constraint. Ainsi, there is a range of other problems explaining the low ag-
ricultural production level in Timor-Leste.
There are no up-to-date ªgures on the amounts of fertilizer and pesticides used in
Timorese agriculture but the available indications point to small amounts. Pour dans-
position, the Timor-Leste Suco Survey reported that only 3 percent of the households
used such inputs in 2001 (Ministry of Planning and Finance and World Bank 2003,
ix), and a 2003 survey in ªve districts revealed that only 29 percent of the farms
used chemical fertilizer and that less than 35 percent used chemical pesticides be-
cause of lack of availability and high prices (Care International 2004, 19).
Investments in irrigation, new seeds, a plow, or a horse are expensive and require
ªnancial capital. Such capital is in scarce supply because farmer incomes are low,
and also because the ªnancial sector is rudimentary. There are only a few banks,
which tend to be located in Dili where they target the international donor commu-
nity and some service sector operators. No commercial banks are found in rural ar-
eas and even if they were, it is likely that low incomes and ill-deªned land rights
would prove to be serious obstacles to borrowing for most farmers. The credit situa-
tion in agriculture has been dismal during the entire independence period. Ainsi, dans
2002, the Japan International Cooperation Agency (JICA 2002) reported that no
farmers had access to credits from banks, 50 percent could borrow from traders, et
14 percent from relatives. An FAO-World Food Programme Study from 2007 bluntly
stated that credit institutions were nonexistent, with minor exceptions (FAO and
World Food Programme 2007, 12) and two years later an IFC survey reported that
loans were typically not available for purchases of farm inputs or improvements or
for trade in farm products, because credit institutions have a problem getting secure
information about borrower risk and because land cannot be used as collateral
(World Bank 2011a, 97–98). Micro ªnance may provide a useful alternative to banks
and some initiatives have been taken by international donors, but it is unclear how
extensive and successful these efforts have been.
3.4 Technologie
Technology in agriculture is related to the use of the inputs described in the pre-
vious section. The choice of a new input, Par exemple, a new variety of seeds, souvent
requires a change in the whole bundle of inputs, such as water and pesticides.
Barlow (2001, 119–120) describes how maize and rice harvests could increase by as
much as 100 percent in Timor-Leste if new and better varieties were to be planted.
He notes, cependant, that such varieties are typically more sensitive to droughts and
pests and require more fertilizers and better storage facilities. This change in inputs
could be described as a new technology package.
79
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
The UNDP (2006, 28) suggests that such changes in technology require a minimum
of four to six years of education of good quality. Malheureusement, the level of educa-
tion in Timor-Leste is low and the quality is poor (Lundahl and Sjöholm 2005). Le
implication is that improvements of the level of education have immediate rele-
vance for the possibilities of introducing a new agricultural technology.
Another area where technology appears to be important is in the processing of crops
like rice and coffee. The UNDP (2006, 30) claims that rice mills are using outdated
technologies. Coffee quality in Timor-Leste suffers from poor processing, often car-
ried out by the farmers themselves, where lack of water, necessary for the wet fer-
mentation, is a major constraint (Barlow 2001, 120). It seems as if there is plenty of
scope for technological improvement both in agriculture and animal husbandry, comme
concluded in a major World Bank (2011un) study on the scope for expansion of agri-
cultural exports in Timor-Leste.
Dans le passé, the Indonesian government took active part in agricultural production
in Timor-Leste. During the occupation, inputs were provided by the government
and output was purchased at set prices. The government also provided credits, stor-
age facilities, and marketing assistance. De plus, it developed an extension service
that was modestly successful, both when it came to introducing new crops and in-
creasing the productivity of the existing ones (World Bank 2011a, 77). The present
government has not yet played any such active role. This is partly caused by an ex-
plicit intention to let the market forces and the private sector (including a number of
nongovernmental organizations), rather than the government, shape agricultural
production and development. Il y a, cependant, few agricultural extension work-
ers in Timor-Leste. This is due both to a lack of trained personnel at the time of the
Indonesian exodus (Timmer 2001, 105) and to the decision (until recently) to restrict
the number of public servants (UNPD 2006, 41).
3.5 Infrastructure and institutions
One of the most important roles of infrastructure and institutions in an economy as
undeveloped as that of Timor-Leste is to assist in the development of the market
système. Farmers need access to markets if they are to abandon subsistence farming.
Markets exist in towns and larger villages but a major problem is a lack of transpor-
tation to markets. Roads were developed reasonably well during the Indonesian oc-
cupation, partly to facilitate the movement of troops across the island, but mainte-
nance has been poor since 1999. Due to the mountainous terrain the roads are
narrow and the speed too slow, which in turn means that the utilization of the truck
ºeet is relatively low. The quality of the road network is bad and consequently
trafªc volumes outside Dili are low. The situation is particularly troublesome during
80
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
the rainy season when many roads are practically impossible to use (World Bank
2011b, Annex 10.1).
Walking is the most common way to move about for most people even when roads
exister. Other means of transportation are either nonexistent or, more commonly, aussi
expensive. Ainsi 80 percent of all farmers have to walk on foot to the nearest market,
which is located two hours away on average (UNDP 2006, 29).
Selling in the market is also difªcult. It is widely argued that farmers have problems
getting access to price information for various crops. Improved communication net-
works including telephones and radios are necessary to facilitate the information
gathering (Timmer 2001, 107). Inadequate or non-existent storage capacity is another
problem. A large share of the harvest is regularly destroyed (UNDP 2006, 30). Un-
other result of the poor access to markets is that many farmers only grow one crop
of rice even where a second harvest would be possible.
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Most farmers use land without clearly deªned title. The attempt of the government
to deªne land rights has been slow and progress has been limited. In the 2012 issue
of the World Bank Doing Business report, Timor-Leste ranks 183 out of 183 des pays
when it comes to registering property (Doing Business 2012, 131). This comes as no
surprise considering that several different, partly conºicting, law systems are in-
volved, with land claims based on traditional rights, Portuguese titles, Indonesian
titles, and occupation as a result of displacement of people voluntarily or by force
by the Indonesian administration (Fitzpatrick 2001; International Crisis Group
2010). The situation is further complicated by the displacements that took place fol-
lowing the 1999 disturbances, when an estimated 250,000 people were driven across
the border to West Timor, and the disturbances in Dili in 2006, when another 150,000
people were displaced. This means that many landholdings have several claimants.
Work has begun on a cadastral survey and a draft land law exists, but it has not yet
been approved by Parliament.
Lack of clear title makes land transactions difªcult and makes it impossible to use
land as collateral for credit, but not only that. Coffee provides an example of how
the lack of clear land rights leads to poor harvests. Low coffee production is to a
large extent caused by neglect in pruning the coffee trees. Pruning increases the
crops but only after a few years, while yields decline for the ªrst two years. Farmers
who are not certain that they will have the right to the crops in the future will there-
fore behave rationally and avoid pruning the trees.1 The lack of other agricultural
1 Another reason for not pruning the trees is that many farmers are so poor that they cannot
81
Asian Economic Papers
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
investment is also partly caused by the failure of the government to provide land ti-
tles. Such failure leads to lower investment both because of the insecurity when it
comes to enjoying the fruits of the investment and because of the difªculty of ob-
taining loans without clearly titled land as collateral.
4. The role of market incentives in agricultural development
It is clear that the government has a role to play when it comes to increasing agricul-
tural production. The most obvious example is the provision of the infrastructure
that will make it possible for farmers to get their products to the market. Another,
much more difªcult, task is the allocation of land rights. It is likely that the lack of
clearly deªned land rights has a detrimental effect on investments in agriculture. UN
third obvious area for government action is extension services.
Timor-Leste is, cependant, not a planned economy but a market economy, bien que
admittedly an embryonic one, since subsistence activities dominate in agriculture.
The question that then arises is whether market incentives can be used to make
Timorese farmers increase their production and sales and use more and better in-
puts. Increasing productivity and output in agriculture is one of the most important
tasks of economic policy in Timor-Leste, because, as we have already dealt with, le
agricultural sector in the foreseeable future will have to serve as a “sink” for the
growing labor force. Conroy (2006) argues that the discussion of “private sector de-
velopment” in Timor-Leste has to take this as its point of departure and suggests
that increased demand for either cash crops or food crops may serve to increase ag-
ricultural production, notably, production for the market. De plus, as in many
other peasant societies, according to Conroy, peasants will not bother to produce for
the market unless they can get access to industrial or other consumer goods that
they cannot produce themselves.
Conroy’s argument implies that the subsistence sector resembles the vent-for-
surplus economy portrayed by Hla Myint (1958), where both labor and land are
unemployed for lack of demand. The economy is producing at some point inside its
production possibility curve, to use a textbook term, and if and when the demand
for its goods increases, combining land and labor in the prevailing ªxed proportions
may serve to bring it quickly to the curve, where production becomes efªcient in the
sense that it will no longer be possible to increase the output of any given commod-
ity without simultaneously reducing that of some other good. There are no longer
any unused resources in the sector.
afford two years of declining production. A better functioning credit system could help
farmers to smooth incomes between years (UNDP 2006, 29).
82
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
Whether such a process will materialize is, cependant, doubtful. In the ªrst place the
land frontier that exists in the economy must be put under the plow, as it were. Le
frontier must be “cleared” before it can be used for production and this is costly in
lui-même (Findlay and Lundahl 1994). Deuxième, in practice it is unlikely that a hand-in-
hand expansion of labor and land can take place. The confused situation with re-
spect to property rights makes it probable that when the agricultural labor force
grows, most of the absorption of this growth will take place on land already under
cultivation. Alors, labor absorption in agriculture will be subject to diminishing re-
turns (c'est à dire., to falling income per head). Troisième, even if land and labor can be com-
bined in ªxed proportions, diminishing returns to labor are likely to set in, because
the land added to cultivation is likely to be either of lower and lower productivity
or of more and more distant location, in the Ricardian fashion.
5. A model of the agricultural household in Timor-Leste
With the given proviso, we may shed some light on the question of whether agricul-
tural “entrepreneurs” will seize the opportunities offered by the market with the aid
of a simple model of farm household behavior (Lundahl and Ndulu 1990). Dans ce
model, households produce food and a cash crop (which they do not consume
themselves) on a given land area. The consumption and production decisions are
hence interdependent. The households maximize their utility given the relative
prices of cash crops, food crops, and purchased goods.2 (The price of purchased
goods is used as the numéraire, c'est à dire., the prices of other goods can be measured in
terms of the number of units of purchased goods they can buy.) Utility maximiza-
tion yields an equilibrium in which the households distribute the available time be-
tween production and leisure, the time devoted to production between cash crops
and food production, and the resulting income between the consumption of food
and purchased goods, all according to their preferences and the prevailing relative
prices. It also determines how much food is sold on the market.
The utility function of the agricultural household is
U (cid:2) U(F, M., Le) ,
(1)
where F denotes food, M purchased goods, and Le leisure.3 Utility is positive and
diminishing for all arguments of the function.
2 An alternative formulation would be to assume that the household maximizes expected
utility subject to a survival constraint. The present formulation does not take uncertainty
into account.
3 Possibly, the household is not interested in leisure. This simpliªes the utility maximization
to a choice between the consumption of food and manufactured goods.
83
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
Food and cash crops are produced using labor and a ªxed quantity of land
according to
qf
(cid:2) qf(Lf) ,
qc
(cid:2) qc(Lc) .
(2)
(3)
These production functions display diminishing returns to labor. The total quantity
of labor (temps) is divided between leisure, food and cash crop production:
L (cid:2) Le
(cid:3) Lf
(cid:3) Lc .
Households maximize their utility subject to equation (4) and to
pmM (cid:2) pf[qf(Lf) (cid:4) F] (cid:3) pcqc(Lc) ,
(4)
(5)
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
where the p’s denote prices. What is available for spending on purchased goods is
the sum of the value of food production, minus what is consumed by the household
lui-même, and the value of cash crop production.
Utility maximization yields the following ªrst-order conditions:
UM(pf/pm) (cid:2) UF ,
ULe (cid:2) UM(pf/pm)qf
L (cid:2) UM(pc/pm)qc
L ,
(6)
(7)
where the superscripts denote ªrst derivatives. In equilibrium, the valuation of
a unit of food must be the same at the margin regardless of whether the house-
hold chooses to sell it to buy purchased goods or to consume it in the household.
Aussi, at the margin the household must obtain the same satisfaction of a unit
of time egardless of whether it is dedicated to leisure, food production, or cash
crop production.
The situation is illustrated in Figure 3. Beginning with the OA curve, this shows the
income-leisure tradeoff for the household. The number of hours available is OB.
Travail (as opposed to leisure) is measured leftwards in the diagram, and income
downwards. The more hours the household works, the higher is its income, lequel
increases at a decreasing rate. Given the preferences of the household for income
and leisure, respectivement, it chooses point C on the tradeoff, working OD hours and
taking out DB hours of free time. This yields a total income of OK, measured in
terms of purchased goods.
84
Asian Economic Papers
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
Chiffre 3. The equilibrium of the farm household
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Source: Authors’ calculations.
The OD hours worked must be distributed between food and cash crop production.
If only the latter is chosen, the maximum output will be OE, one of the two end-
points on the household’s production possibility curve. If the household specializes
in food production instead, the maximum output is given by the other endpoint of
the curve, OF. The production possibility curve is drawn on the assumption of a
given factor (labor) endowment, and shows the different possible combinations of
food and cash crops that can be obtained with the aid of this endowment. The actual
choice of production is determined by the relative price of the two crops, as given by
the price line IJ. This line is tangent to the production possibility curve at G, which is
where the value of output is maximized at the given prices.
85
Asian Economic Papers
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
The output combination given by G gives a farm household income of OI, measured
in terms of cash crops, or OJ, if we choose to measure in terms of food instead.
Given the relative price prevailing between food and purchased goods, this trans-
lates into an income of OK, in terms of the latter, our numéraire. The only thing that
remains to be determined is the consumption of the household, given this income,
represented by the budget line JK. Given the preferences of the household for the
two goods, the consumption point is L, where ML units of the purchased goods and
OM units of food are consumed. Ce, à son tour, leaves a food surplus of MH, which is
sold in the market.
5.1 Farm household response to market incentives
Suivant, we will use our model to examine the proposition offered by John Conroy
(2006, 20): that Timorese farmers may be expected to increase production for any of
the following three reasons:
1. Increased prices on cash crops;
2. Increased prices on food crops; et
3. Reduced prices (increased availability) on goods not manufactured by the farm-
ers but purchased from outside.
In the present work, we do not make any assumptions as to where the price changes
come from, but they are likely to be intimately connected with, Par exemple,
infrastructural development. Par exemple, better roads are likely to increase the net
price fetched by the farmers both for cash and food crops while at the same time
they should have to pay less for what they buy from the outside.
We will next examine the probable effects of each one of these price changes with
the aid of our model.
(cid:5) 0)
5.2 Increased prices of cash or food crops
Let us begin with what happens when the price of cash crops increases (dpc
while the other two prices are kept constant. The price increase serves to rotate the
income–leisure tradeoff in Figure 3 counterclockwise, since the value of the mar-
ginal product of labor in the production of cash crops increases. For any given labor
effort in agriculture, household income will increase. En même temps, leisure will
become more expensive in terms of income forgone. We have an income effect and a
substitution effect, and it will not be possible to reach a general conclusion of
whether more hours will be devoted to agriculture than before, or the number of lei-
sure hours will increase. Si, cependant, leisure is an inferior good, as hinted by
Conroy, the number of hours worked will increase. This is a quite realistic case in a
86
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
poor economy. Households have plenty of idle time. Should income possibilities im-
prove, it is quite likely that the farm household prefers to work more and not less.
Leisure does not even have to be inferior. It is enough that the substitution effect is
strong enough to swamp the increased demand for leisure at given prices.
What will happen to the production of the two goods? The ªrst-order condition
(equation (7)) may be rewritten as:
(pf/pm)qf
L (cid:2) (pc/pm)qc
L .
Differentiating equation (4) yields:
dLf
(cid:2) (cid:4)(dLc
(cid:3) dLe) ,
and from equation (8), allowing pc to change and keeping pm and pf constant (ni-
malizing all three prices (cid:2) 1, at the outset), we obtain
(8)
(9)
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
qf
LLdLf
(cid:2) qc
LLdLc
(cid:3) qc
Ldpc .
Combining equations (9) et (10) gives us
(cid:4)(qf
LL (cid:3) qc
LL)dLc
(cid:2) qc
Ldpc
(cid:3) qf
LLdLe
(cid:5) 0 ,
(10)
(11)
(cid:6) 0, because dpc
(cid:5) 0. If the rise in the
(cid:5) 0 and the second derivatives of the production
provided that dLe
functions are negative. By the same token it must be that dLc
price of cash crops leads to less leisure, the production of these crops must increase.
Even if dLe is positive, the production of cash crops may increase, if the price rise is
grand. The production of food crops may increase as well, in the case where the re-
duction of the hours devoted to leisure exceeds the increase in the number of hours
devoted to cash crop production. Enfin, what happens to the marketed surplus of
food crops is uncertain. The on-farm demand for food will increase if the production
of cash crops, and hence income, increases, because the relative price of food and
purchased goods remains constant, but food production may also increase.
In the same way, it may be demonstrated that an increase in the price of food will
lead to increased food production, provided that leisure is reduced or provided that
the increase in the price of food is large. What will happen to on-farm consumption
and the marketed surplus of food is not clear. When incomes rise in terms of the
purchased goods the farm households will demand more of both these goods and
food at given relative prices. There is also a substitution effect due to the increase of
87
Asian Economic Papers
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
the relative price of food, cependant. This serves to reduce the consumption of food
and increase that of purchased goods. The net outcome of this is unclear and will
depend on the income elasticity of demand for food products among the farm
households themselves.
Normally, we should expect Engel’s Law to operate—namely, when incomes rise,
less and less of the income increase will be devoted to food consumption, pour que le
share of the household budget spent on food will decrease as income increases. Dans
Timor-Leste, cependant, this is not necessarily the case. Various empirical investiga-
tions have shown that households experience a shortage of food between November
and April (c'est à dire., for some four months every year; Lundahl and Sjöholm 2005, 15–16;
2008b, 20). Ainsi, given the low income level and the large share of the population
living in poverty, it is far from certain that Engel’s Law is operative. It is not possible
to rule out the possibility that an increase in the price of food will lead to a reduction
of the marketed surplus.
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
5.3 Cheaper purchased goods
Enfin, we investigate whether a cheapening of the goods that the farm households
purchase from the outside will serve as a stimulus to increased production and sales
(in the case of food). Encore, we differentiate equation (8), but this time holding pf
and pc constant, while allowing pm to fall. This yields
qf
LLdLf
(cid:4) qf
Ldpm
(cid:2) qc
LLdLc
(cid:4) qc
Ldpm .
(12)
In equilibrium the value of the marginal product of labor in food production must
equal that in cash crop production (remembering that we have normalized all
prices (cid:2) 1 at the outset). Hence the second terms on both sides of the equality sign
in equation (12) are equal. What remains is
qf
LLdLf
(cid:2) qc
LLdLc .
(13)
Either the production of food and cash crops will both increase, or both decrease.
Rewriting equation (9) comme
dLe
(cid:2) (cid:4)(dLf
(cid:3) dLc)
(14)
shows that the crucial determinant here is what happens to leisure as purchased
goods become cheaper. Because we have chosen the price of purchased goods as our
numéraire, making these goods cheaper amounts to increasing farm household in-
88
Asian Economic Papers
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
come. The income–leisure tradeoff in Figure 3 will rotate counterclockwise, exactly
as when the price of cash crops or food increased. Once more, we have an income ef-
fect and a substitution effect, and if the net outcome of these is to reduce leisure, le
production possibility curve will shift outwards and the production of both cash
and food crops will increase. In the opposite case, it will fall. Encore, what will hap-
pen to the marketed surplus of food crops is not certain. The same considerations as
before apply.
5.4 The importance of outside alternatives
So far, we have considered farm households with no options to work outside of ag-
riculture. The Household Survey carried out in 2001 (see Lundahl and Sjöholm 2005,
14) reported two signiªcant ªndings: (1) Among those individuals who were in the
labor force, those belonging to households whose heads were limited to farm em-
ployment were considerably poorer than when the heads worked in wage employ-
ment, household business, or other outside ventures; (2) presque 70 percent of all
Timorese belonged to families with no or only small possibilities of obtaining in-
come from outside agriculture.
This clearly points to desirability of creating employment outside the agricultural
sector. In the short run, this could for example take the form of public works during
the off-peak season in agriculture. In the longer run, a private sector will develop.
Smallholders in the developing countries often derive their income from a variety of
sources, and this serves to increase their standard of living. This ªnding can easily
be incorporated into our model. In Figure 4, the possibility of earning a given out-
side wage equal to w/pm, when measured in terms of purchased goods, has been in-
corporated. The household keeps working in agriculture until the value of the mar-
ginal product of labor there falls to the level given by the constant outside wage. À
this point (B), the income–leisure curve becomes a straight line. Thereafter the re-
maining hours worked are spent in wage employment, up to point C. The income
from this must be added to that from farm work. Hence the total income line will lie
outside IJ and outside the budget line JK. The incorporation of outside employment
changes our conclusions.
Let us begin with the case of increased prices of cash crops. When pc increases, as be-
fore, the income–leisure tradeoff rotates counterclockwise, from OA to OA1. Le
value of the marginal product increases in agriculture, and more hours will be
worked there. Outside work will no longer begin at B (or D), but at B1 or (D1). Le
total number of hours worked will, cependant, decrease. Provided that leisure is not
89
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
Chiffre 4. An increase in the relative price of cash crops
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Source: Authors’ calculations.
an inferior good, points C1 and E1 lie to the right of C and E, respectivement, as long as
some outside work takes place both before and after the price increase. The reason is
that the substitution effect disappears. Leisure is no more expensive at the margin
after the price increase than before, because the marginal valuation is given by the
wage rate and not by the price of cash crops, and the wage rate does not change. All
that remains is the income effect, and this makes for increased leisure. Income in-
creases as well, but as a result of the reallocation of work hours between wage labor
and farm work. D'autre part, should leisure be inferior, C1 will be to the left of
C and E1 to the left of E. Work will increase both inside and outside of agriculture at
the expense of leisure.
Turning to the allocation of work hours between cash and food crop production,
equation (12) may now be rewritten as
(pf/pm)qf
L (cid:2) (pc/pm)qc
L (cid:2) w/pm,
(15)
90
Asian Economic Papers
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
where the wage rate is given in terms of purchased goods. Aussi, the available labor
time has to be distributed among leisure, crop production, and outside work. Ce
changes equation (4) à
L (cid:2) Le
(cid:3) Lf
(cid:3) Lc
(cid:3) Lm
(16)
Differentiating equation (15) when pc changes and the other two prices and the wage
rate in terms of purchased goods (w/pm) are held constant (with pf
the outset) yields
(cid:2) 1 à
(cid:2) pm
(cid:2) pc
ou
et
qf
LLdLf
(cid:2) qc
LLdLc
(cid:3) qc
Ldpc
(cid:2) 0
dLc
(cid:2) (cid:4)(qc
L/qc
LL)dpc
(cid:5) 0
dLf
(cid:2) 0.
(17)
(18)
(19)
The output of cash crops increases and that of food remains constant. Ici, price in-
centives work unequivocally, and because all cash crops are sold in the market, dehors-
side sales will increase as well. The marketed surplus of foodstuffs, on the other
main, will be reduced. Farm household income has increased, and both food prices
and the price of purchased goods remain constant. Hence there is only the income
effet. The demand for both food and purchased goods among farm households will
increase, but food output remains constant. The marketed surplus of food must
therefore shrink.
The analysis is analogous for the case of increased food prices. There will be more
leisure and larger food production and cash crop production will remain constant.
Dans ce cas, cependant, we don’t know with certainty what will happen to the mar-
keted surplus of food. The price of the latter good increases and the substitution ef-
fect will be reintroduced. Possibly, on-farm consumption will be reduced and more
food will be sold outside.
The conclusions will change also when the price of purchased goods is reduced (mais
w/pm remains constant). The income–leisure tradeoff again rotates counterclock-
wise, more leisure is enjoyed, and less work takes place outside the farm and more
inside. Équation (12), à son tour, becomes
91
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
et
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
qf
LLdLf
(cid:4) qf
Ldpm
(cid:2) qc
LLdLc
(cid:4) qc
Ldpm
(cid:2) 0
dLc
(cid:2) (qc
L/qc
LL)dpm
(cid:5) 0
dLf
(cid:2) (qf
L/qf
LL)dpm
(cid:5) 0 .
(20)
(21)
(22)
(cid:6) 0, so the production of both cash crops and food will increase. The farm
dpm
households will increase their consumption of purchased goods, and possibly, mais
not with certainty, that of food as well, because food becomes more expensive in
terms of purchased goods. Cependant, because the production of foodstuffs increases
aussi, the net result of the cheapening of purchased goods may be both increased
leisure, at the expense of outside work (provided that leisure is a superior good), dans-
creased on-farm consumption of food, and increased sales not only of cash crops but
also of food.
5.5 Policy implications
The model analysis has some policy implications. The ªrst one is that we cannot be
certain that price incentives will necessarily work for farm households that have no
outside opportunities. The increased income opportunities may be converted to
more leisure instead of increased output. D'autre part, given the widespread
poverty in the countryside, this is perhaps less likely. Alors, in the case of higher
cash crop prices, more output will be put on the market. The case of food crops is
different, because these are consumed also by the farmers themselves, et, given
the regular periodic food scarcity, an increased output is likely to be absorbed to a
certain (unknown) extent by increased on-farm consumption. Access to cheaper
purchased goods will increase the production of both types of crops, provided that
it reduces leisure, but we don’t not know with certainty whether this will result in
more food in the marketplace or not.
The second policy implication is that once farm households get access to outside in-
come opportunities, agricultural production is likely to increase as a result of price
incentives. As long as leisure is not an inferior good, all three price changes will re-
sult in more leisure, but at the expense of outside work. The increases of the value of
the marginal product of labor in agriculture that are due to the price changes will
ensure that the output of the crop whose price increases will increase as well, et
when purchased goods become cheaper, the production of both types of crops will
expand. The marketed surplus of food will shrink when the price of cash crops in-
creases, but not necessarily in the other two cases, where not only the on-farm con-
92
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
sumption but also the production of food increases. (If leisure is inferior, both out-
side work and work in agriculture will increase. The effects on agricultural
production will be the same.)
Ainsi, altogether, it appears likely that price incentives stand a better chance to work
once the farmers have access to outside income earning opportunities as well. Aussi,
in that case, improved access to purchased consumer goods may serve as an impor-
tant stimulus to agricultural production. Ce, à son tour, may be important for non-
agricultural enterprises, which often perceive that their operations are constrained
by insufªcient demand. The situation to a certain extent resembles that of the
chicken and the egg. If outside goods are available, farmers may produce more, et
this may provide a market for domestic modern enterprises, but unless the latter
provide outside goods in the ªrst place, there may be no response from the farmers.
The analogy is not perfect, cependant. The initial stimulus could come from imported
goods, and once domestic entrepreneurs see this, they may develop substitutes for
imports. But then, on the other hand, a business environment conducive to entrepre-
neurship must be created, and here, Timor-Leste has some way to go (Lundahl and
Sjöholm 2009b).
The Timorese government seems to be aware of the importance of job creation and
has tried to increase publicly funded employment since 2007. The number of jobs in
the public sector is increasing, which represents a change from a previous deliberate
attempt to keep public employment below 20,000 people. The most visible employ-
ment effects have come from government-funded infrastructure projects, lequel
have beneªted 40,000–60,000 Timorese annually since 2007, often through short-
term employment for the rural population (UNDP 2011).
6. Conclusions
This article has dealt with the problem of how to achieve a higher future income and
living standard in Timor-Leste. In the longer run, that will presumably be the task
mainly of a modern industry or service sector, but at the present time four-ªfths of
all Timorese are subsistence peasant farmers, and in the absence of a modern sector,
in the short and medium term, agriculture will have to continue to act as a sink in
terms of employment.
This fact makes it natural to focus on what determines production and incomes in
agriculture. In the ªrst part of our discussion we used a “production function ap-
proach,” which allowed us to focus on the inputs used in agriculture. Land is a
scarce production factor and little capital is used, among other things due to a gen-
93
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
eralized lack of credit. The technological level is low, not only because of the lack of
capital, but also because of the low educational standard of the farmers and the lack
of government support in such areas as extension and transportation.
The agricultural sector in Timor-Leste is to a large extent a subsistence sector, où
the agricultural households consume most of what they produce. In the future,
cependant, the market orientation of the sector is likely to increase. Timor-Leste will
presumably undergo the same process of rural–urban migration and urbanization as
the rest of the developing countries. Ce, à son tour, means that change, for better or
for worse, will presumably have to come via the market mechanism.
In the second part of our analysis we hence developed a model of an agricultural
household, which allowed us to ªnd out the likely effects of changes in the prices of
food and cash crops and industrial goods on agricultural production and incomes,
crop mix, leisure, farm household consumption of food and industrial goods, et
sales of food crops and cash crops not consumed by the farm households. Incentives
may come from increased prices of farm products and reduced prices of industrial
goods. The effects of these changes are not altogether clear-cut. Much depends on
how the farmers value leisure and on whether the farm household has access to out-
side earning opportunities as well. Introducing wage-earning opportunities may be
important, because in this case, whatever increased leisure farm households may
want to enjoy will take place though a reduction in outside work rather than farm
production. The production of at least one agricultural commodity will increase
(both in the case of a cheapening of manufactured goods). Thus the objective of in-
creasing the living standard of Timorese farmers may in part be achieved via in-
creased earning opportunities outside agriculture.
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
Les références
Barlow, Colin. 2001. The Rural Economy and Institutions in East Timor. In East Timor: Develop-
ment Challenges for the World’s Newest Nation, edited by Hal Hill and João M. Saldanha, pp. 110–
114. Singapore and Australia National University: ISEAS and Asia Paciªc Press.
Care International Timor Leste. 2004. Rice Marketing Survey Report Undertaken in Manatutu,
Maliana, Suai, Viqueque and Oecusse. Available at http://www.jica.go.jp/easttimor/english/
activities/pdf/report.pdf. Accessed 20 Août 2012.
Conroy, John. 2006. Timor-Leste Acess to Finance for Investment and Working Capital. Monde
Bank Report No. 37736. Washington, CC: The World Bank.
Doing Business. 2012. Doing Business 2012: Doing Business in a More Transparent World. Wash-
ington, CC: The World Bank.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
94
Asian Economic Papers
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
FAO (Food and Agricultural Organization) and World Food Programme. 2007. Special Report:
FAO/WFP Crop and Food Supply Assessment Mission to Timor-Leste. 21 Juin. Rome. Available at
ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/010/ah866e/ah866e00.pdf. Accessed 20 Août 2012.
Findlay, Ronald, and Mats Lundahl. 1994. Natural Resources, “Vent-for-Surplus” and the Sta-
ples Theory. In From Classical Economics to Development Economics, edited by Gerald M. Meier,
pp. 68–93. Houndmills and London: Macmillan.
Fitzpatrick, Daniel. 2001. Property Rights in East Timor’s Reconstruction and Development. Dans
East Timor: Development Challenges for the World’s Newest Nation, edited by Hal Hill and João M.
Saldanha, pp. 177–192. Singapore and Australia National University: ISEAS and Asia Paciªc
Presse.
Fox, James J. 2001. Diversity and Differential Development in East Timor: Potential Problems
and Future Possibilities. In East Timor: Development Challenges for the World’s Newest Nation, éd-
ited by Hal Hill and João M. Saldanha, pp. 155–176. Singapore and Australia National Univer-
ville: ISEAS and Asia Paciªc Press.
International Crisis Group 2010. Managing Land Conºict in Timor-Leste. Asia Brieªng No. 110;
9 Septembre. Dili and Brussels: International Crisis Group.
JICA. 2002. Study on Integrated Agricultural Development of East Timor: Development Plan Report.
Dili: Japan International Cooperation Agency.
Lewis, W. Arthur. 1954. Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour. Manches-
ter School of Social and Economic Studies 10:139–191.
Lundahl, Mats, and Benno Ndulu. 1990. Incentives and Food Production in Tanzania. In Incen-
tives and Agriculture in East Africa, edited by Mats Lundahl, pp. 87–122. London and New York:
Routledge.
Lundahl, Mats, and Fredrik Sjöholm. 2005. Poverty and Development in Timor-Leste. Sida Coun-
try Economic Report 2005:3. Stockholm: Sida.
Lundahl, Mats, and Fredrik Sjöholm. 2007. A Year of Turmoil: Timor-Leste 2006–2007. Sida Coun-
try Economic Report 2007:5. Stockholm: Sida.
Lundahl, Mats, and Fredrik Sjöholm. 2008un. The Oil Resources of Timor-Leste: Curse or Bless-
ing? The Paciªc Review 21:67–86.
Lundahl, Mats, and Fredrik Sjöholm. 2008b. Limping on Three Legs: The Development Problem of
Timor-Leste. Sida Country Economic Report 2008:5. Stockholm: Sida.
Lundahl, Mats, and Fredrik Sjöholm. 2009un. Population Growth and Job Creation in Timor-
Leste. Journal of the Asia Paciªc Economy 14:90–104.
Lundahl, Mats, and Fredrik Sjöholm 2009b. Entrepreneurship in Timor-Leste. In The Handbook
of Research on Asian Entrepreneurship, edited by Léo-Paul Dana, Mary Han, Vanessa Ratten, et
Isabell Melpe. Aldershot, Hants: Edward Elgar.
Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry, and Fisheries (MAFF). 2004. National Food Security Policy for
Timor-Leste. Dili: Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries.
Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry, and Fisheries (MAFF). 2007. First National Report. Land
Degradation in Timor-Leste. Février. Available at http://www.sprep.org/att/IRC/eCOPIES/
Countries/Timor_Leste/3.pdf. Accessed 20 Août 2012.
95
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Improving the Lot of the Farmer
Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries (MAFF). 2009. Directorate of Agribusiness: Proªles
for Maize and Rice. Dili: Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry, and Fisheries.
Ministry of Health and National Statistics Ofªce, ACIL Australia, University of Newcastle and
the Australian National University. 2004. Timor-Leste Demographic and Health Survey. Key Find-
ings. Dili: Ministry of Health.
Ministry of Planning and Finance and World Bank. 2003. Poverty in a New Nation: Analysis for
Action. Dili and Washington, CC: Ministry of Planning and Finance and World Bank.
Myint, Hla. 1958. The Classical Theory of International Trade and the Underdeveloped Coun-
tries. Economic Journal 68:317–337.
Timmer, Peter C. 2001. Food Policy in East Timor: Linking Agriculture, Economic Growth and
Poverty Alleviation to Achieve Food Security. In East Timor: Development Challenges for the
World’s Newest Nation, edited by Hal Hill and João M. Saldanha, pp. 99–109. Singapore and
Australia National University: ISEAS and Asia Paciªc Press.
UNDP (United Nations Development Programme). 2002. East Timor Human Development Report
2002. Ukun Rasik A’an/The Way Ahead. Dili: UNDP.
UNDP (United Nations Development Programme). 2006. Timor-Leste Human Development
Report 2006: The Path Out of Poverty. Integrated Rural Development. Dili: UNDP.
UNDP (United Nations Development Programme). 2011. Timor-Leste Human Development
Report 2011: Managing Natural Resources for Human Development. Dili: UNDP.
World Bank. 2011un. Timor-Leste: Expanding Near-Term Agricultural Exports. Diagnostic Trade
Integration Study (DTIS) Prepared for the Integrated Framework. (In Two Volumes) Volume I:
Main Report. Report No. 61814-TP. Juin. Washington, CC: The World Bank.
World Bank. 2011b. Timor-Leste: Expanding Near-Term Agricultural Exports. Diagnostic Trade
Integration Study (DTIS) Prepared for the Integrated Framework. (In Two Volumes) Volume II:
Report Annexes. Report No. 61814-TP. Juin. Washington, CC: The World Bank.
World Bank. 2012. World Development Indicators. Washington, CC: The World Bank. Available
at http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators. Accessed
8 Août 2012.
96
Asian Economic Papers
je
D
o
w
n
o
un
d
e
d
F
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
je
r
e
c
t
.
m
je
t
.
/
e
d
toi
un
s
e
p
un
r
t
je
c
e
–
p
d
/
je
F
/
/
/
/
/
1
2
2
7
1
1
6
8
3
2
5
2
un
s
e
p
_
un
_
0
0
2
1
1
p
d
.
F
b
oui
g
toi
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
7
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3