Automation, AI & Work
Laura D. Tyson & John Zysman
We characterize artificial intelligence as “routine-biased technological change on ste-
roids,” adding intelligence to automation tools that substitute for humans in physical
tasks and substituting for humans in routine and increasingly nonroutine cognitive
tasks. We predict how AI will displace humans from existing tasks while increasing
demand for humans in new tasks in both manufacturing and services. We also ex-
amine the effects of AI-enabled digital platforms on labor. Our conjecture is that AI
will continue, even intensify, automation’s adverse effects on labor, including the po-
larization of employment, stagnant wage growth for middle- and low-skill workers,
growing inequality, and a lack of good jobs. Though there likely will be enough jobs to
keep pace with the slow growth of the labor supply in the advanced economies, we are
skeptical that AI and ongoing automation will support the creation of enough good
jobs. We doubt that the anticipated productivity and growth benefits of AI will be
widely shared, predicting instead that they will fuel more inequality. Yet we are opti-
mistic that interventions can mitigate or offset AI’s adverse effects on labor. Ultimately,
how the benefits of intelligent automation tools are realized and shared depends not
simply on their technological design but on the design of intelligent policies.
A mazing new automation and digital technologies are transforming work
and the economy.1 Artificial intelligence is the latest tool in a toolkit of
“automation” technologies that perform tasks previously performed by
humans, often more cheaply, faster, and better.
Most humans depend on income from work for their livelihoods, and we focus
on how AI, like other forms of automation, affects work. A key question is how AI
and AI-enabled intelligent tools will impact the supply of and access to good jobs
that provide middle-class earnings, safe working conditions, legal protections,
social insurance and benefits, and career-building opportunities. In the advanced
market economies and democracies that are the focus of this essay, political and
social stability depends on the availability and accessibility of good jobs.
With supportive fiscal and monetary policies adequate to maintain high lev-
els of employment, it is likely that there will be enough jobs to keep pace with the
slow growth of the labor supply in these economies. But we are skeptical that AI
along with ongoing automation will support the creation of enough good jobs. And
we are doubtful that the anticipated productivity and growth benefits of AI will be
256
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
© 2022 by Laura D. Tyson & John Zysman Published under a Creative Commons Attribution- NonCommercial 4.0 International (CC BY-NC 4.0) license https://doi.org/10.1162/DAED_a_01914
widely shared, predicting instead that they will fuel income and wealth inequali-
ty. Yet we are optimistic that wise interventions can change the trajectory of AI’s
adverse effects on labor. Comparative experiences highlighted in this essay reveal
that both policies, like social insurance, training and education, and taxation, and
institutions, like collective bargaining, can accelerate, offset, moderate, or inten-
sify these effects.
Contemporary AI uses advanced computation to automate specific tasks at or
above human cognitive capacity. Its development rests on advances in computing
power and hardware, the proliferation of vast data sets, and evolving algorithms
for analyzing and drawing statistical inferences and predictions.2 Powered by ma-
chine learning (ML), recent AI breakthroughs are achieving human-comparable
results across an expanding range of human tasks.3 Despite remarkable advanc-
es, however, current AI applications remain narrow and task specific, with little
ability to transfer “learning” from one problem to another. Narrow AI can dis-
place humans in low-level cognitive demand tasks that are repetitive, data intensive,
optimization-based, and asocial, but it cannot yet substitute for humans in most
high-level cognitive demand tasks involving reasoning, real-world knowledge, judg-
ment, and social interactions.
Narrow AI is also impacting human tasks both by adding intelligence to robots
and production systems and by powering digital platforms that facilitate trans-
actions between buyers and sellers. In a self-reinforcing cycle of data collection,
analysis, and prediction, AI is driving the growth of digital platforms like Amazon
for selling goods, Netflix for selling video services, and Uber and Upwork for sell-
ing labor services. Indeed, large tech platform companies in the United States and
China, with massive amounts of data, extensive digital platforms, and relative-
ly small employment compared with their revenues, currently account for about
two-thirds of all business investment in AI.
“Artificial general intelligence” (AGI) has no clear definition, no clear time
frame, is not yet a matter of business and policy concerns, and is therefore not our
focus.4 Instead, we concentrate on how narrow but rapidly evolving AI applica-
tions are likely to affect labor and livelihoods over the coming decade. Since even
narrow AI applications are not yet widespread, our analysis by necessity draws on
evidence about the impacts of other forms of automation on labor in the advanced
industrial countries during the last three decades.
P redictions about the future effects of AI are replete with uncertainties both
about the pace and scope of future scientific breakthroughs and about the
pace and breadth of AI deployment. Scientific advances determine whether a
human task is technically automatable, but they do not determine whether it will be auto-
mated. That depends on deployment decisions. In market economies, businesses make
most of these decisions shaped by their strategies and the market, institutional,
257
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
151 (2) Spring 2022Laura D. Tyson & John Zysman
and policy environments in which they operate. High taxes on labor relative to
taxes on machinery and software, for example, have been a significant driver of
business investments in automation technologies. Nonetheless, their deployment
has been gradual because of substantial lags in the development of organizational
capacities required for their effective utilization.5
Both historical evidence and economic logic indicate that on its current tra-
jectory, AI will continue, intensify, and accelerate automation’s adverse effects on
key labor market trends in the advanced economies. These effects include the po-
larization of employment and wages, slow wage growth for middle- and low-skill
workers, a significant premium in the wages of highly educated workers, a decou-
pling of wage growth from productivity growth, a decline in labor’s share of value
added, and growing income inequality.
Automation is not the only force behind these trends. Globalization, outsourc-
ing, the decline in unionization and collective bargaining coverage, and the grow-
ing monopsony or “wage-setting” power of businesses are also significant fac-
tors.6 These factors in turn have been enabled or reinforced by automation. Glo-
balization and outsourcing, for example, have been turbocharged by robots and
digitization in logistics, transportation, and communication.7 By enabling the
outsourcing of routine jobs to low-wage locations, networked technologies and
automation, underpinned by the digital revolution, have propelled globalization,
decreasing employment and constraining wage growth in manufacturing and
tradable services in the advanced economies.
Yet while these factors have been at play in all of the advanced countries, there
have been important differences among them in the consequences for labor. The
varied outcomes have resulted in part from differences in policies, institutions,
and societal norms of fairness. Strong competitive economies like Germany, Swe-
den, Canada, and Denmark have experienced the same technological and global-
ization forces as the United States, but their workers have fared much better.8
Examining tasks within occupations is a widely used optic to understand the
impact of automation on labor, and we organize our analysis with this approach.
Occupations encompass numerous tasks, only some of which are automatable or
AI-susceptible.
Like other automation tools, AI impacts human tasks through three broad
effects: the displacement effect, or the decrease in demand for labor in tasks that
are automated; the productivity effect, or the increase in the demand for labor in
nonautomated tasks; and the reinstatement effect, or the creation of new tasks for
labor. Over time, but at a highly uncertain pace, automation’s displacement ef-
fects are offset to some extent by both its productivity and reinstatement effects.9
The displacement effects can be immediate, significant, and palpable, and are
themselves negative for employment and labor’s share in value added. In contrast,
the productivity and reinstatement benefits can take years, even decades, to mate-
258
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Dædalus, the Journal of the American Academy of Arts & SciencesAutomation, AI & Work
rialize with significant frictional and structural unemployment, wage losses, and
growing inequality along the way. In the long run–that ill-defined concept fre-
quently used by economists–automation, productivity growth, and rising em-
ployment and wages move together.
But automation always involves disruption and, with it, winners and losers.
Trade-offs can and do persist for “shorter” time horizons relevant to businesses,
workers, citizens, and political leaders, and they have economic, social, and po-
litical consequences. History is replete with evidence that the social and political
costs of labor market disruptions triggered by technological change can be signif-
icant.10 And while displacement effects may hit particular locations or regions,
productivity and reinstatement benefits can occur elsewhere: the costs often fall
in one place and the benefits in another, complicating politics and policy.11
During the last thirty years, there is evidence that while automation’s displace-
ment effects have accelerated and intensified, its productivity and reinstatement
effects have been slower to materialize and smaller than expected.12 The social
and economic dislocations have grown, while the offsetting benefits have not been as robust
or rapid as anticipated and have not been broadly shared. In the United States, for ex-
ample, despite growing automation and computerization of work, productivity
growth slowed by nearly half to an annual rate of 1.5 percent during the last half
century, and industries that led in the use of new information and communication
technologies did not perform better in terms of total factor productivity, output,
or employment growth. Nor is the United States alone: other advanced industri-
al economies have also experienced slowing productivity growth, the causes of
which remain uncertain and robustly debated.13
Much of the automation during the last three decades is often called “routine-
biased technological change,” or RBTC, because it has substituted for humans in
routine physical and increasingly routine cognitive tasks while increasing the de-
mand for humans in nonroutine tasks. Both routine manual and routine cognitive
occupations as a share of employment have fallen over the last thirty years. RBTC
has been particularly important in automating tasks in structured, predictable en-
vironments like automobile production in factories and bookkeeping in offices.
We characterize AI as “RBTC on steroids” for two reasons. First, AI is adding
intelligence to robots and other forms of automation that substitute for humans
in routine and increasingly nonroutine physical tasks–think assembly-line pro-
duction and warehousing. Second, AI is substituting for humans in a widening ar-
ray of both routine and increasingly nonroutine cognitive tasks.14 Cognitive tasks
that are currently technically feasible for AI tend to be routine, data-intensive, and
asocial (such as customer support, basic office support, and insurance underwrit-
ing). Physical tasks that are technically feasible for AI also tend to be routine, data-
intensive, optimization-based, and asocial, and require limited dexterity and a
structured environment (like assembly-line inspection or fruit harvesting). Most
259
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
151 (2) Spring 2022Laura D. Tyson & John Zysman
high-level cognitive demand tasks in which inputs and outputs are not easily quan-
tifiable with data, and which require both social interaction and cross-domain
thinking, complex strategy, or creativity (such as the work of business and health
professionals, teachers, and artists) are not directly in the crosshairs of current AI.15
If, as we conjecture, AI is RBTC on steroids, then its future effects on labor will
be similar to the effects on labor from other forms of RBTC automation during
the past thirty years. The first of these effects is the “polarization” of employment
and, to a lesser extent, of wages. Many of the occupations hollowed out by RBTC
over the previous three decades have been in manufacturing, which provided
good jobs for millions of middle-skill, middle-wage workers. Polarization is re-
flected in a decline in the share of middle-skill occupations in total employment
and increases in the employment shares of both low-skill and high-skill occupa-
tions, with the largest gains in the latter.16 Although RBTC has been polarizing, it
has been “upgrading” or “upskilling” in the sense that the decline in middle-skill
occupations has been largely offset by an increase in high-skill occupations as
shares of total employment.17
Polarization, in turn, has contributed to widening wage gaps among work-
ers, with slow, stagnant, or even negative wage growth for workers whose occu-
pations have been displaced by automation, and wage growth for those whose
occupations have been enhanced by productivity gains or by the creation of new
tasks. Earnings inequality has grown across the advanced industrial economies,
largely driven by the rising pay gap or education premium between workers with
a college-level education or rigorous training (like apprenticeships in Germany)
whose skills have been complemented by RBTC and those with lower levels of ed-
ucation or training whose skills have been displaced.18
As a result of its sizable displacement and polarization effects, RBTC automa-
tion has also been a factor behind the decoupling of wage growth from productivi-
ty growth.19 In theory, in competitive labor markets, wage growth should be com-
mensurate with productivity growth in the long run, but productivity growth has
outpaced both average and median wage growth over the past three decades. As
noted earlier, the long run can be very long indeed, and there are large and lengthy
aberrations along the path to getting there. Moreover, labor markets are usually
not competitive, as narrowly defined by economists, and the sharing of produc-
tivity gains with workers depends not only on market forces but on the relative
power of workers and employers. Relative power in turn is often reflected in tax
and social policies and in institutions like corporate governance rules that favor
owners over workers.
The decoupling of wage and productivity growth has contributed to a decline
in labor’s share of national income.20 Indeed, automation has been a major driv-
er of the decline in labor share most acute in manufacturing, and within manu-
facturing, most acute in industries undergoing rapid automation. In addition,
260
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Dædalus, the Journal of the American Academy of Arts & SciencesAutomation, AI & Work
a declining labor share of national income has been mirrored in a rising capital
share, further increasing income inequality, since capital returns are concentrated
at the upper end of the income distribution.
The slow growth of pretax market incomes for the bottom 95 percent of wage
earners has been the main driver of increasing income inequality in the advanced
market economies over the past half century, and automation has played a major
role.21 The United States has been an outlier: no other advanced industrial econ-
omy has experienced an equally large rise in income inequality or equally severe
wage stagnation for rank-and-file workers. Both eroding union coverage and a de-
clining real minimum wage have been important factors behind the comparative-
ly large gap between productivity growth and median wage growth, the compar-
atively large earnings inequalities by education, and the significant real wage de-
cline for low-educated male workers in the United States. In contrast, in Germany,
another large competitive market economy experiencing the same RBTC automa-
tion and globalization forces, broad collective bargaining rights, works councils,
a generous social insurance system, a robust training system, and a national mini-
mum wage have mitigated the adverse effects of automation on the supply of good
jobs and have fostered more inclusive growth.22
Overall, RBTC automation has contributed to rising income inequality through
a number of channels. It has resulted in stagnant or falling real wages for middle-
and low-skill workers, favoring wages of high-skill workers complemented by
automation; it has driven a large and persistent gap between wage growth and
productivity growth; it has reduced labor’s share and increased capital’s share in
value added; and it has produced “winner-take-all” income gains for superstar
innovators and superstar firms with significant product market and monopsony
power, contributing to rising income inequality both among them and between
them and their workers.23
All of these factors are “market” explanations of wage stagnation and income
inequality that reflect changes in the demand for different types of labor and cap-
ital resulting from RBTC automation. We are concerned that these market factors
are likely to persist and indeed may strengthen as RBTC on steroids reduces the
demand for labor with low and middle skills (and wages) performing both phys-
ical and cognitive routine tasks while increasing the demand for labor with skills
required for nonroutine tasks of both types.
At the same time, we recognize that AI is likely to make human work more pro-
ductive in some existing tasks and to create new tasks requiring human skills that
cannot be replaced by AI capabilities. Uniquely human skills not susceptible to AI
currently include social/interpersonal skills (teachers, care and health care work-
ers, physical therapists, and hairdressers); physical skills in unpredictable envi-
ronments (construction workers and plumbers); and general intelligence skills
required for nonroutine tasks and problem-solving (management and artists).
261
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
151 (2) Spring 2022Laura D. Tyson & John Zysman
For many occupations, the future of work is likely to involve growing interdepen-
dence between human skills and AI skills: for example, between the interpersonal
skills of doctors and teachers with the complementary AI skills of data analysis,
diagnostics, and prediction. Such complementary or partnership occupations in
turn are likely to require high-level education and/or technical training for the
human partners. Overall, such occupational changes are likely to fuel wage and
income inequality between those workers whose skills are displaced by AI and
those whose skills are complemented. A key but unanswered question is how the
rewards from work will be shared between humans and their partner intelligent
tools, between labor and the owners and creators of these tools.
S o far, we have focused on how AI is affecting labor demand through the au-
tomation of tasks and occupations. Now we broaden our focus to consider
how AI is affecting labor through enabling digital platforms that are creat-
ing new tasks and new forms of organizing work.24 We believe that digital plat-
forms, the use of which surged during the COVID-19 pandemic, will expand rapid-
ly. To predict AI’s future effects on labor, therefore, it is necessary to look through
the lens of digital platforms. AI is enabling three types of digital platforms.
• Platforms for selling goods (such as Amazon and Netflix) recast what tasks are
performed by humans and where. Accelerated by COVID-propelled chang-
es in business practices to reduce workplace density and provide contactless
service to customers, transactions continue to move from in-person, brick-
and-mortar retail to e-commerce and digital platforms, with tasks shifting
from shop floors to warehouse operations and long- and short-haul delivery
and transportation.
• Platforms for labor services (such as Upwork, Lyft, and TaskRabbit), which uti-
lize algorithms and real-time data to match workers with tasks, are having a
growing impact on labor across industries. These platforms cover a wide range
of tasks spanning nonroutine cognitive work like accounting and software
work, nonroutine physical and technical work like electrical and plumbing
services, and routine personal services like transportation and care.25 Work-
ers typically are matched with tasks for multiple clients, usually on a tempo-
rary project basis. Such work is often referred to as “gig work.” Gig workers,
including the digital assembly-line “ghost workers” who provide much of the
human intelligence behind AI software, are part of the “on-demand gig econ-
omy.”26 And in response to COVID, new work-related platforms from Google
to Zoom are expanding to facilitate remote or hybrid work for cognitive tasks.
• Platforms for renting out assets (such as Airbnb and BlaBlaCar) also offer new
labor and income opportunities, even while they alter the character of work
and the skills required for tasks.
262
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Dædalus, the Journal of the American Academy of Arts & SciencesAutomation, AI & Work
Platform-mediated work is growing rapidly as a share of nonstandard employ-
ment arrangements (including independent contractors, temporary and on-call
workers, and part-time workers) that already account for 25–31 percent of the
working age populations in the advanced economies.27 More than half of those
participating in such arrangements use income from them to supplement their
income from other sources. The platform-mediated gig portion of nonstandard
employment arrangements is still small, accounting for an estimated 1–3 percent
of total employment, but it is expanding quickly.28
Gig workers lack the legal and social protections provided in standard employ-
ment contracts, resulting in precarious jobs with low and unstable incomes, limited
access to social insurance, minimal training and career development opportunities,
exposure to health and safety risks, and low to zero collective bargaining rights.
As AI-enabled platforms transform relationships between employers and
workers, new ways to finance and deliver social and legal protections are required
to make gig and other platform jobs “good jobs.” When COVID sharply reduced
the demand for gig workers, most of the advanced economies added temporary
measures, like pandemic unemployment benefits in the United States, to compen-
sate workers for lost income.
Pre-COVID, many governments in Europe and a few U.S. states were already
working on permanent measures to protect or empower gig workers. The United
Kingdom, for example, added a new “worker” category, distinct from both the tra-
ditional employee category and the self-employed category, to its labor law. Some
European countries are exploring extending social protections usually associat-
ed with standard employment contracts–such as unemployment and disability
insurance, health coverage, and parental leave–to gig workers on labor services
platforms.29 Such benefits could be provided and financed through new “portable
benefits programs,” allowing workers to accumulate benefits on a prorated basis
for time worked for different employers.30
Looking to the future, two forces will shape the demand for human labor in dif-
ferent tasks and occupations: the demand for goods and services that people want
and the capabilities of intelligent tools and systems, empowered by AI, to produce
and deliver them. Based on these two forces, over the next decade, we anticipate
shifts in the composition of employment in the advanced industrial economies
from occupations like office support, production, and warehousing that consist of
many routine tasks to occupations in health care, education, technology, and the
arts that encompass many nonroutine tasks.31 The upskilling of employment is
likely to continue with job growth concentrated in high-wage occupations and job
declines in low- and middle-wage ones, further polarizing the labor market and fu-
eling wage inequality. And the displacement and transition costs for workers who
lose their jobs to AI and automation and who require different skills for new jobs
are likely to be substantial, raising the question of who should bear these costs.32
263
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
151 (2) Spring 2022Laura D. Tyson & John Zysman
These predicted shifts in occupations and their labor market effects are likely
in both manufacturing and services that together account for more than 90 per-
cent of employment. Manufacturing has been the locus of the hollowing out of
“good” middle-skill, middle-wage jobs during the past thirty years, driven by ro-
bots, RBTC, and globalization. While manufacturing employment has fallen as a
share of total employment, manufacturing output has not fallen nearly as sharply
as a share of GDP. There have been significant productivity gains from automa-
tion, but they have not been broadly shared. A disproportionate share has gone
to capital, not to workers, as evidenced by both the rising gap between produc-
tivity growth and wage growth and the fall in labor’s share of value added. More-
over, the declines in manufacturing employment and wages have fallen hardest on
workers in the lower half of the earnings distribution, on workers with less than a
college degree, and on locations or regions in which manufacturing was a signifi-
cant share of economic activity.
Similar disparities in the distribution of both displacement costs and produc-
tivity benefits are likely as AI drives further automation of manufacturing. Overall,
the hollowing out of manufacturing jobs is likely to continue but also to be smaller
than what occurred during the last thirty years. A new wave of AI-powered auto-
mation with increasingly programmable, semi-dexterous, and interconnected ma-
chines will optimize production systems. The resulting changes are likely to affect
manufacturing employment by optimizing tasks that have already been automated
and by creating new complementary tasks with required new skills for workers to
operate new smarter systems. The pace at which manufacturing tasks are automat-
ed will depend not only on evolving AI capabilities but also on the improved dex-
terity of robots and production systems. Overall, AI is not likely to add significant
risk of additional job displacement to “shop-floor” manufacturing workers, but it
is likely to displace workers doing routine cognitive tasks in back offices.33
Based on both rising incomes and changing demographics, the demand for
services will remain robust in the advanced industrial societies. Indeed, services
already account for most (more than 80 percent) employment and almost all em-
ployment growth during the last several decades. Service occupations run the
gamut from highly paid health and business professionals to middle-wage educa-
tors to low-wage retail clerks and hospitality workers. Given the diverse character
of the service sector, we highlight briefly some of AI’s implications in two large
service industries: retail and health.
A rtificial intelligence is transforming the retail industry across its value
chain. On the demand side, businesses are shifting from traditional in-
store channels to e-commerce channels, especially digital platforms, to
anticipate demand and personalize the customer experience. On the supply side,
AI is being applied to improve inventory forecasts, optimize merchandising and
264
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Dædalus, the Journal of the American Academy of Arts & SciencesAutomation, AI & Work
product assortment, and automate warehousing and store operations. Overall
employment in retail is likely to continue to decline, but the demand for humans
in routine and nonroutine cognitive tasks in such areas as customer service, man-
agement, and technology deployment and maintenance is likely to increase. In
contrast, routine manual jobs such as cashiers, drivers, packers, and shelf stock-
ers are projected to decline, reducing low- to middle-wage job opportunities for
workers with only a secondary education. In both manufacturing and services,
the pace of change in AI- enabled drones and autonomous vehicles will impact the
pace at which human tasks and wages in short-haul and long-haul transportation,
two major middle-wage occupations, are affected.
In the health care sector, job growth is likely to remain strong. Indeed, both pre and
post COVID, the health sector has topped the list of projected job growth in the ad-
vanced economies. Health care jobs cover a broad range of skills and incomes, from
low-skill, low-wage jobs like orderlies and home care assistants through middle-
skill, middle-wage jobs like lab technicians and paramedics to high-skill jobs like
nurses, dentists, radiology technologists, and physicians. All of these job categories
are projected to grow to keep pace with rising demand for health care services.
Within health care, AI is likely to complement the demand for high-wage work-
ers performing nonroutine tasks requiring specialized skills and education while
substituting for workers performing routine tasks. In particular, AI applications
are likely to substitute for humans in data-dependent cognitive tasks in adminis-
trative and office support activities and patient relationship management while
increasing the demand for humans in work performed by health professionals like
nurses, doctors, physical therapists, and dentists whose responsibilities require
high-level cognitive and/or highly skilled physical and social interaction tasks.
The automation of administrative and data collection tasks, further enabled by
telemedicine platforms, could be transformative for nurses who spend on average
a quarter of their time on such duties, empowering them to use AI- informed re-
sults to offer more real-time health advice, diagnosis, and treatment.34
Many health care occupations are likely to require collaboration between hu-
mans with the requisite social skills and intelligent tools with the requisite data
capabilities to deliver state-of-the art personalized services at scale. The scope for
collaboration between humans and AI in health care is already apparent in the uti-
lization of AI-enabled robots to address the interrelated demographic challenges
of aging and shrinking populations. Japan, for example, is leading the way in robot
use in tasks in nursing homes and hospitals, both to fill gaps in the supply of human
labor available for these tasks and to complement the humans required to do them.
T hroughout this essay, we have focused on the effects of AI and automation
on the composition of demand for human labor in tasks, occupations, and
jobs. Yet, as the example of Japan’s adoption of robots in health care illus-
265
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
151 (2) Spring 2022Laura D. Tyson & John Zysman
trates, employment, wages, and good jobs depend not only on the demand for hu-
man labor but also on its supply.35 All of the industrial economies face a slowdown
in the growth of their working age populations, albeit to differing degrees, and
this is likely to result in shortages and upward pressure on wages both in occupa-
tions and jobs that are not currently susceptible to substitution by AI and in those
that are complemented or enabled by it. As labor markets recover from COVID,
there is already concern in the United States and in several European countries
about future shortages of workers with the skills and education required to meet
demand in growing sectors like health care and software engineering. Such short-
ages in turn are likely to accelerate innovation, investment, and deployment of
AI-enabled automation technologies to substitute for human labor.
AI and the intelligent tools and systems it enables will automate many routine
tasks, change existing tasks, and create new tasks for humans, often involving new
forms of human and machine collaboration and new forms of work organization.
There will be–indeed there already are–both winners and losers in this process of
ongoing structural change. It is not sufficient to assert that as AI technologies trans-
form work, there will ultimately be broad economic gains that are widely shared.
That is not a technologically determined outcome but rather a societal choice. To
foster both economic growth and the social and economic equity on which their
prosperity and political stability depend, the advanced market economies must de-
velop policies to share the disruption costs and productivity benefits of AI broadly,
consistent with societal norms of fairness.
The availability and accessibility of good jobs should be core policy goals, yet
achieving them is not trivial. To maximize the odds for success and to transform
all jobs into good jobs, three broad types of policy interventions are warranted.
First are lifelong education and training policies to equip workers with the skills
they need for access to good jobs, along with active labor market policies to help
them transition to these jobs. Second is the extension of social benefits and legal
protections to cover workers in all businesses, including platform businesses. And
third is a combination of income-support policies, including minimum wages, tax
credits for work, and basic income supplements, to raise the after-tax earnings of
workers who remain in low-wage jobs–including many routine service jobs in
leisure and hospitality, health care, and childcare, many of them held by women
and low-educated workers–to livelihood levels.36
Finally, it is important to emphasize that the effects of AI on work are not tech-
nologically determined but depend on the incentives of both those leading AI re-
search and innovation and those investing in AI deployment. The prevailing nar-
rative behind AI innovation and deployment in the business and research commu-
nities, a narrative particularly pronounced in the United States, where decisions
reflect shareholder interests and workers have limited voice in business decisions,
focuses on AI’s ability to outperform humans, not on the creation of good jobs.
266
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Dædalus, the Journal of the American Academy of Arts & SciencesAutomation, AI & Work
This narrative has been fostered by tax policies that raise the cost of labor and
reduce the cost of capital, encouraging businesses to focus on automation tech-
nologies that reduce employment and cut labor costs without offsetting labor
productivity growth. R&D tax incentives and other forms of government support
for research in labor-saving technologies have reinforced the narrative, but well-
designed policies could change it.37
Ultimately, how the economic benefits of intelligent machines and tools are
realized and shared depend not on their technological design but on the design of
intelligent policies needed for an inclusive AI era.38
authors’ note
The authors are grateful to the Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation, the German
Federal Ministry of Labour and Social Affairs (BMAS), and the American Acade-
my in Berlin for their generous support for this work. Our research was a product
of collaboration with the Hertie School, Humboldt Institute for Internet and Soci-
ety, Weizenbaum Institute, and WZB Berlin Social Science Center. We thank Dafna
Bearson and Camille Carlton for their outstanding research assistance.
about the authors
Laura D. Tyson, a Fellow of the American Academy since 2002, is Distinguished
Professor of the Graduate School at the Haas School of Business and Founder and
Co-Faculty Director of the Sustainable and Impact Finance Initiative at the Univer-
sity of California, Berkeley. She also chairs the Board of Trustees at UC Berkeley’s
Blum Center for Developing Economies. She served in the Clinton administration
as the Chair of the Council of Economic Advisers and as Director of the National
Economic Council. She is the author of many publications, including Who’s Bashing
Whom: Trade Conflicts in High-Technology Industries (1992).
John Zysman is Professor Emeritus in the Department of Political Science at the
University of California, Berkeley. His publications include The Highest Stakes: The
Economic Foundations of the Next Security System (1992), Manufacturing Matters: The Myth
of the Post-Industrial Economy (1987), and Governments, Markets, and Growth: Finance and
the Politics of Industrial Change (1983).
267
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
151 (2) Spring 2022Laura D. Tyson & John Zysman
endnotes
1 For a comprehensive analysis of automation’s effects, see David Autor, David Mindell,
and Elisabeth Reynolds, The Work of the Future: Building Better Jobs in an Age of Intelligent Ma-
chines (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2020); and James Manyika, Susan Lund, Michael
Chui, et al., Jobs Lost, Jobs Gained: Workforce Transitions in a Time of Automation (New York:
McKinsey Global Institute, 2017).
2 Thomas W. Malone, Daniela Rus, and Robert Laubacher, “Artificial Intelligence and the
Future of Work” (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Future of Work, 2020); Michael I. Jordan,
“Artificial Intelligence–The Revolution Hasn’t Happened Yet,” Harvard Data Science Re-
view 1 (1) (2019); Gary Marcus, “The Next Decade in AI: Four Steps Towards Robust
Artificial Intelligence,” arXiv (2020), https://arxiv.org/abs/2002.06177; John Zysman
and Mark Nitzberg, Governing AI: Understanding the Limits, Possibilities, and Risks of AI in an
Era of Intelligent Tools and Systems (Washington, D.C.: Wilson Center, 2020); Mark Nitz-
berg and John Zysman, “Algorithms, Data, and Platforms: The Diverse Challenges
of Governing AI,” BRIE Working Paper 2021-1 (Berkeley: Berkeley Roundtable on the
International Economy, University of California, Berkeley, 2021); and Kevin Roose,
Futureproof: 9 Rules for Humans in the Age of Automation (New York: Random House, 2021).
3 Machine learning is the primary computer science breakthrough enabling contemporary
AI. ML is a form of context-dependent statistical inference, in which algorithms are
trained on vast amounts of data and improve (“learn”) automatically through training.
Deep Learning is a machine learning method that adjusts “weights” in multiple layers
of artificial neural networks (ANNs) based on training data, and has powered the recent
breakthrough, human-comparable AI results.
4 While not dismissive of the possibility of AGI, many scholars agree that the focus of policy
and regulation should be on the impacts of narrow AI. See, for example, Gary Marcus
and Ernest Davis, Rebooting AI: Building Artificial Intelligence We Can Trust (New York: Pan-
theon Books, 2019); and Erik Brynjolfsson, Tom Mitchell, and Daniel Rock, “What Can
Machines Learn, and What Does It Mean for Occupations and the Economy?” AEA
Papers and Proceedings 108 (2018): 43–47.
5 Erik Brynjolfsson, Daniel Rock, and Chad Syverson, “Understanding and Addressing the
Modern Productivity Paradox” (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Future of Work, 2020).
6 Maarten Goos, Alan Manning, and Anna Salomons, “Explaining Job Polarization: Rou-
tine-Biased Technological Change and Offshoring,” American Economic Review 104 (2)
(2014): 2509–2526.
7 Laura D. Tyson and Michael Spence, “Exploring the Effects of Technology on Income
and Wealth Inequality,” in After Piketty: The Agenda for Economics and Inequality, ed. Heath-
er Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong, and Marshall Steinbaum (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
University Press, 2017), 170–208.
8 Anke Hassel and Bruno Palier, eds., Growth and Welfare in Advanced Capitalist Economies: How
Have Growth Regimes Evolved? (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2021); Autor et al., The
Work of the Future; and Christian Dustmann, “Trade, Labor Markets, and the China
Shock: What Can be Learned from the German Experience?” in Combating Inequality:
Rethinking Government’s Role, ed. Olivier Blanchard and Dani Rodrik (Cambridge, Mass.:
MIT Press, 2021), 117–124.
9 Daron Acemoglu and Pascual Restrepo, “Automation and New Tasks: How Technology
Displaces and Reinstates Labor,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 33 (2) (2019): 3–30. The
268
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Dædalus, the Journal of the American Academy of Arts & SciencesAutomation, AI & Work
following lectures summarize the conclusions, with supporting data, on ongoing re-
search by Acemoglu and Restrepo on automation, AI, and the effects on labor. Daron
Acemoglu, “Tasks, Automation and Labor Market,” presentation and lecture at Gorman
Conference & Lectures 2020, virtual event, October 12, 2020; and Daron Acemoglu,
“New Tasks, Good Automation and Bad Automation: Implications for the Future of
Work,” presentation and lecture at Gorman Conference & Lectures 2020, virtual event,
October 13, 2020.
10 This is well documented in Carl Benedikt Frey, The Technology Trap: Capital, Labor, and Power
in the Age of Automation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2019); and Barry
Eichengreen, The Populist Temptation: Economic Grievance and Political Reaction in the Modern
Era (New York: Oxford University Press, 2020).
11 For evidence on the regional disparities of automation’s effects in the United States, see
Susan Lund, James Manyika, Liz Hilton Segel, et al., The Future of Work in America: People
and Places, Today and Tomorrow (New York: McKinsey Global Institute, 2019). See also
Mark Muro, Countering the Geographical Impacts of Automation: Computers, AI, and Place Dis-
parities (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 2019).
12 Daron Acemoglu, “Could We and Should We Reverse (Excessive) Automation?” in
Combating Inequality: Rethinking Government’s Role, ed. Olivier Blanchard and Dani Rodrik
(Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2021), 163–170.
13 Erik Brynjolfsson, Seth G. Benzell, and Daniel Rock, “How to Solve the Puzzle of Produc-
tivity Growth,” Tech Stream, Brookings Institution, May 21, 2021.
14 Daron Acemoglu, David Autor, Jonathon Hazell, and Pascual Restrepo, “AI and Jobs: Ev-
idence from U.S. Vacancies,” VoxEU, March 3, 2021, https://voxeu.org/article/ai-and
-jobs-evidence-us-vacancies; Michael Webb, “The Impact of Artificial Intelligence on
the Labor Market,” working paper (2019); Erik Brynjolfsson, Tom Mitchell, and Dan-
iel Rock, “What Can Machines Learn, and What Does It Mean for Occupations and the
Economy?” AEA Papers and Proceedings 108 (2018): 43–47; and Edward W. Felten, Manav
Raj, and Robert Seamans, “A Method to Link Advances in Artificial Intelligence to Oc-
cupational Abilities,” AEA Papers and Proceedings 108 (2018): 54–57.
15 Kai-Fu Lee, AI Superpowers: China, Silicon Valley, and the New World Order (Boston: Houghton
Mifflin Harcourt, 2018); Kai-Fu Lee and Chen Qiufan, AI 2041: Ten Visions for Our Future
(New York: Currency, 2021); Autor et al., The Work of the Future; and Ajay Agrawal, Josh-
ua Gans, and Avi Goldfarb, eds., The Economics of Artificial Intelligence: An Agenda (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 2019).
16 The share of middle-skill occupations in total employment declined (11 percent), high-
skill occupations grew (9 percent), and low-skill occupations grew (3 percent) be-
tween the mid-1990s to the late 2010s across OECD countries. See Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development, OECD Employment Outlook 2020: Worker Secu-
rity and the COVID-19 Crisis (Paris: OECD Publishing, 2020), Figure 4.1, https://doi.org/
10.1787/1686c758-en.
17 Georgios Petropoulos, “Occupational Change, Artificial Intelligence and the Geography
of EU Labor Markets,” Bruegel Working Paper 03 (Brussels: Bruegel, 2020).
18 Florian Hoffmann, David S. Lee, and Thomas Lemieux, “Growing Income Inequality in
the United States and Other Advanced Economies,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 344
(4) (2020): 52–78; and Autor et al., The Work of the Future.
269
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
151 (2) Spring 2022Laura D. Tyson & John Zysman
19 David Autor and Anna Salomons,“Is Automation Labor-Displacing? Productivity Growth,
Employment, and the Labor Share,” Working Paper 24871 (Cambridge, Mass.: Nation-
al Bureau of Economic Research, 2018); Mathilde Pak and Cyrille Schwellnus, “Labour
Share Developments Over the Past Two Decades: The Role of Public Policies,” OECD
Economics Department Working Papers No. 1541 (Paris: OECD Publishing, 2019); Cyrille
Schwellnus, Andreas Kappeler, and Pierre-Alain Pionnie, “The Decoupling of Median
Wages from Productivity in OECD Countries,” International Productivity Monitor 32 (2017);
and Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, “Decoupling of Wag-
es from Productivity: What Implications for Public Policies?” OECD Economic Outlook 2
(2018).
20 On factors that contribute to the declining labor share, see Bennet Berger and Guntram
B. Wolff, “The Global Decline in the Labour Income Share: Is Capital the Answer to
Germany’s Current Account Surplus?” (Brussels: Bruegel, 2017); James Manyika, Jan
Mischke, Jacques Bughin, et al., “A New Look at the Declining Labor Share of Income in
the United States” (New York: McKinsey Global Institute, 2019); and Caterina Astarita
and Gaetano D’Adamo, “Inequality and Structural Reforms: Methodological Concerns
and Lessons from Policy” (Brussels: Directorate-General for Economic and Financial
Affairs, European Commission, 2017), https://ideas.repec.org/p/euf/dispap/071.html.
21 Lucas Chancel, “Ten Facts about Inequality in Advanced Economies,” in Combating
Inequality: Rethinking Government’s Role, ed. Olivier Blanchard and Dani Rodrik (Cam-
bridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2021), 3–30.
22 Laura Tyson, “Automation and the Future of Work in Germany: A Summary of Re-
search and Policy Recommendations?” Governing Work in the Digital Age Project
Working Paper (Berlin: Hertie School, 2020), https://digitalage.berlin/wp-content/
uploads/2021/12/2021_Tyson-WP1-Paper-FINAL-1.pdf; and Laura Tyson, “The Future
of Work in Germany,” The Berlin Journal 33 (2019).
23 Tyson and Spence, “Exploring the Effects of Technology on Income and Wealth In-
equality”; and Anton Korinek and Joseph E. Stiglitz, Artificial Intelligence and Its Implications
for Income Distribution and Unemployment (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2019).
24 Dafna Bearson, Martin Kenney, and John Zysman, “Measuring the Impacts of Labor in
the Platform Economy: New Work Created, Old Work Reorganized, and Value Creation
Reconfigured,” Industrial and Corporate Change 30 (3) (2021), https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/
dtaa046; and Martin Kenney, Dafna Bearson, and John Zysman, “The Platform Econo-
my Matures: Measuring Pervasiveness and Exploring Power,” Socio-Economic Review 19
(4) (2021), https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwab014.
25 Jacques Bughin, Eric Hazan, Susan Lund, et al., Skill Shift: Automation and the Future of the
Workforce (New York: McKinsey Global Institute, 2018).
26 Mary Gray and Siddharth Suri, Ghost Work: How to Stop Silicon Valley from Building a New
Global Underclass (Boston: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt, 2019); and Daisuke Wakaba-
yashi, “Google’s Shadow Workforce: Temps Who Outnumber Full Time Employees,”
The New York Times, May 28, 2019, https://www.nytimes.com/2019/05/28/technology/
google-temp-workers.html?searchResultPosition=1.
27 Jonathan I. Dingel and Brent Neiman, “How Many Jobs Can be Done at Home?” Journal
of Public Economics 189 (2) (2020).
28 Susan Lund, Anu Madgavkar, James Manyika, et al., The Future of Work after COVID-19
(New York: McKinsey Global Institute, 2021).
270
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Dædalus, the Journal of the American Academy of Arts & SciencesAutomation, AI & Work
29 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Employment Outlook 2020;
and International Labour Organization, “The Role of Digital Labour Platforms in
Transforming the World of Work,” in World Employment and Social Outlook 2021 (Geneva:
International Labour Organization, 2021), https://www.ilo.org/global/research/global
-reports/weso/2021/lang–en/index.htm.
30 Libby Reder, Shelly Steward, and Natalie Foster, Designing Portable Benefits: A Resource Guide
for Policymakers (Washington, D.C.: Aspen Institute, 2019); and Steven Hill, Raw Deal:
How the “Uber Economy” and Runaway Capitalism Are Screwing American Workers (New York:
St. Martin’s Press, 2015).
31 Three changes in business and consumer practices in response to COVID-19 are likely to
reinforce these changes in the composition of labor demand: the expansion of hybrid
work for both routine and nonroutine cognitive tasks; the expansion of e-commerce,
reducing demand for workers in low-wage routine tasks in retail/leisure/restaurants
with partially offsetting increases in demand for workers doing warehousing, delivery,
and other logistics tasks; and the acceleration of AI-enabled automation and digitali-
zation of tasks to reduce workplace density and social interaction. See Lund et al., The
Future of Work after COVID-19.
32 For other recent studies predicting the future effects of AI on work, see Jason Furman
and Robert Seamans, “AI and the Economy,” NBER Working Paper 24689 (Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2018); Marguerita Lane and Anne
Saint-Martin, “The Impact of Artificial Intelligence on the Labour Market: What Do
We Know So Far?” OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers No. 256
(Paris: OECD Publishing, 2021); and Michael Chui, Artificial Intelligence–The Next Digital
Frontier? (New York: McKinsey and Company Global Institute, 2017), 3–6.
33 Moreover, as AI enables sensors and data, it will create new manufacturing tasks for new
manufactured products that are packaged and sold as “services for everything” bun-
dles, combining physical goods with ongoing maintenance, upgrading, and replace-
ment services.
34 Thomas Davenport and Ravi Kalakota, “The Potential for Artificial Intelligence in
Healthcare,” Future Healthcare Journal 6 (2) (2019): 94; and Ari Bronsoler, Joseph Doyle,
and John Van Reenen, “The Impact of New Technology on the Healthcare Workforce”
(Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Work of the Future, 2020).
35 Hal Varian, “Automation Versus Procreation (aka Bots Versus Tots),” VoxEU, March 30,
2020, https://voxeu.org/article/automation-versus-procreation-aka-bots-versus-tots.
36 For an insightful framework distinguishing preproduction, production, and postproduc-
tion policies for inclusive growth, see Dani Rodrik and Stefanie Stantcheva, “Econom-
ic Inequality and Insecurity: Policies for an Inclusive Economy” (report prepared for
commission chaired by Olivier Blanchard and Jean Tirole on major future economic
challenges, Republic of France, 2021), 193–328.
37 Daron Acemoglu and Pascual Restrepo, “The Wrong Kind of AI? Artificial Intelligence
and the Future of Labour Demand,” Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 13 (1)
(2019): 25–35.
38 Erik Brynjolfsson and Andrew McAfee, The Second Machine Age: Work, Progress, and Prosperity
in a Time of Brilliant Technologies (New York: W. W. Norton & Company, 2016); and Laura
D’Andrea Tyson, “Intelligent Machines and Displaced Workers” (Emeryville, Calif.:
Berkeley Research Group, 2014).
271
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
d
a
e
d
a
r
t
i
c
e
–
p
d
/
l
f
/
/
/
/
1
5
1
2
2
5
6
2
0
6
0
5
6
7
d
a
e
d
_
a
_
0
1
9
1
4
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
151 (2) Spring 2022Laura D. Tyson & John Zysman
Download pdf