Unburnable Fossil Fuels and
Climate Finance: Compensation
for Rights Holders
(cid:129)
Martí Orta-Martínez, Lorenzo Pellegrini, Murat Arsel,
Carlos Mena, and Gorka Muñoa*
Abstrakt
To limit the increase in global mean temperature to 1.5°C, CO2 emissions should be
capped at 440 gigatons. To achieve this, um 89 Prozent, 59 Prozent, Und 58 Prozent
of existing coal and conventional gas and oil reserves, jeweils, need to remain
unburned. This implies an economic cost for fossil fuel rights owners, and any successful
climate policy will rely on resolving the distributional challenge of how to allocate the
right to use the remaining burnable reserves. We discuss the possibility of compensating
rights holders of unburnable oil and gas reserves, producing the first estimates of the
financial resources needed to secure full compensation. We estimate that approximately
US$ 5,400 Milliarde (109) would be needed. Despite the vast amounts required, compen- sation is nevertheless economically feasible. We suggest a Keynesian “whatever it takes” approach for climate action, combining partial compensation for unburnable fuels and investment in low-carbon technologies to drastically reduce emissions in the rapidly closing window of opportunity before 2030. Moving Forward Debate on Unextractable Fossil Fuels The Paris Agreement aims to limit global warming to well below 2°C, preferably to 1.5°C, compared to preindustrial levels. To limit the increase in global mean temperature, the future anthropogenic carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions should not exceed a certain amount—the “remaining carbon budget” (Matthews et al. * This work was supported by two grants from the Spanish Ministerio de Ciencia, Innovación y Universidades—RYC-2016–21366 (MCIU/AEI/ FSE, UE) and RTI2018-095949-BI00 (MCIU/ AEI/FEDER, UE)—and by the All Eyes on the Amazon program. We are thankful to the editors of Global Environmental Politics, Steven Bernstein, Matt Hoffmann, and Erika Weinthal, and to managing editor, Susan Altman, for their support and guidance. Globale Umweltpolitik 22:4, November 2022, https://doi.org/10.1162/glep_a_00688 © 2022 vom Massachusetts Institute of Technology 15 l D o w n o a d e d von h t t p : / / Direkte . m i t . l / / e d u g e p a r t i c e – p d l f / / / / / 2 2 4 1 5 2 0 5 8 3 9 8 g e p _ a _ 0 0 6 8 8 p d . l f b y g u e s t t o n 0 7 S e p e m b e r 2 0 2 3 16 (cid:129) Unburnable Fossil Fuels and Climate Finance 2021; Meinshausen et al. 2009). For a 50 percent probability of limiting warm- ing to 1.5°C, the remaining carbon budget from 2020 onward has been esti- mated at 440 gigatons of CO2 (GtCO2) (Matthews et al. 2021). For a 2°C limit, the remaining carbon budget amounts to 1,370 GtCO2 for a 50 percent prob- ability (Matthews et al. 2021). Jedoch, the CO2 potential emissions contained in present estimates of global fossil fuel reserves represent a staggering 2,900 GtCO2, or approximately 2 times higher than the 2°C carbon budget and approximately 7 times higher for a 1.5°C limit (Matthews et al. 2021; McGlade and Ekins 2015; Welsby et al. 2021). Reserves are producible resources that are “commercially viable,” and current estimates show that their extraction is incompatible with the commitments to limit average global warming (Matthews et al. 2021; McGlade and Ekins 2015; Welsby et al. 2021). In prac- tice, and based on the opportunity costs of different fossil fuel reserves, um 89 Prozent, 59 Prozent, Und 58 percent of existing coal, Gas, and oil reserves, jeweils, would need to remain under the soil to limit global warming to 1.5°C (for an extended explanation of the assumptions and associated uncer- tainties of these estimates and the risks from reserves accountability, see Green and Kuch 2022; Welsby et al. 2021). Despite the urgency to limit global warming (Lenton et al. 2019), the clar- ity of the concepts of remaining carbon budget, and the associated fossil fuel extraction budget, climate change mitigation policies have so far failed to abate extraction (Höhne et al. 2020), and global demand for and consumption of fos- sil fuels are still ramping up, as are CO2 emissions (International Energy Agency 2021). With global CO2 emissions at 42 GtCO2 per year and increasing, the remaining budget for 1.5°C warming (440 GtCO2) could be completely exhausted by 2030. Jedoch, oil, Gas, and coal reserves are worth approximately US$ 27,000 Milliarde (109) (Jakob and Hilaire 2015), and most fossil fuel pro-
ducers still push for increased extraction, including through emission-heavy
fuels such as brown coal, bitumen, and shale gas, and invest in new infrastruc-
ture to expand fuel supply. Von 2024, fossil fuel firms plan to invest a further US$ 1,400 billion in new projects (Global Gas and Oil Network 2019). Climate change mitigation policies have so far largely focused on interven- tions to reduce the demand for fossil fuels (z.B., carbon taxes, cap-and-trade schemes, and energy efficiency standards), while policies aimed at restricting their supply (z.B., extraction taxes, fossil fuel subsidy removal, moratoria or quotas on extraction, tradable production allowances, and restrictions on the access to credit) have been largely neglected (Lazarus and van Asselt 2018; Pellegrini et al. 2021). Jedoch, there has been a recent surge in academic and sociopolitical interest in supply-side fossil fuel policies (Erickson et al. 2018; Lazarus and van Asselt 2018; Pellegrini and Arsel 2022; Piggot et al. 2020), spearheaded by social mobilizations (Martínez-Alier 2022). Leaving unburnable fuels untapped implies an economic cost for fossil fuel rights owners, and any successful climate policy will crucially hinge on resolving the distributional challenge of how to equitably and cost-efficiently allocate the l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / Direkte . m i t . l / / e d u g e p a r t i c e – p d l f / / / / / 2 2 4 1 5 2 0 5 8 3 9 8 g e p _ a _ 0 0 6 8 8 p d . l f b y g u e s t t o n 0 7 S e p e m b e r 2 0 2 3 M. Orta-Martínez, L. Pellegrini, M. Arsel, C. Mena, and G. Muñoa (cid:129) 17 right to extract the remaining burnable reserves (Jakob and Hilaire 2015; Kartha et al. 2018; Muttitt and Kartha 2020; Pye et al. 2020). Insbesondere, the benefits of allocating a larger share of extraction rights to developing countries have been advocated based on ethical considerations but also questioned on efficiency, sozial, and environmental grounds (Pye et al. 2020). The question of how to share fairly the costs of leaving unburnable fuels untapped has been discussed in terms of historical responsibility for accumulated extraction and current capa- bility to withstand the burden of the energy transition costs (Kartha et al. 2018). Ethical principles have been laid out for the need for international support that depend jointly on the social costs of transitioning away from fossil fuels and the capability to bear these costs for each country (Muttitt and Kartha 2020). Our contribution is to bring to the fore the possibility of compensating rights holders of oil and gas reserves to keep them underground indefinitely, to produce the first estimate of the financial resources needed to secure compen- sation on a global scale, and to address the question of how to source such funds. Given the substantial amounts needed for full compensation of rights holders over oil and gas reserves, we also discuss the ethical dimension of the right to compensation that is contingent on responsibility and capability. The Cost of Compensation The economic cost of nonextraction for fossil fuel rights owners can be esti- mated by their opportunity cost, das ist, the net benefit that could have been enjoyed if they had been extracted as compared to leaving them untouched. The total opportunity cost of the global unburnable fuels can be calculated per country as a function of the national reserves of the different fossil fuel cat- egories, the production costs, the fossil fuel national royalty rates, the future fos- sil fuel prices, and future discount rates, unter anderen. Reserves estimates are available per country, although they fluctuate over time (depending on prices, the cost of available technologies, and new discoveries), and rights holders have an incentive to overstate them (Grün, this issue; Laherrère et al. 2022). Royal- ties are the main source of revenues from fossil fuel extraction for resource owners (Busby et al. 2011) and can be considered an appropriate (albeit imper- fect) proxy to estimate the opportunity cost of leaving fossil fuels untapped. In the case of state-owned companies (national oil companies, or NOCs), the opportunity cost might be closer to the difference between the price and the cost of producing a barrel oil equivalent (BOE). NOCs’ production represents 55 percent of total oil and gas production worldwide (Natural Resource Gover- nance Institute 2019), Und, zum Beispiel, the production cost of oil in the Middle East is just around US$ 10 pro Barrel (Rystad Energy 2020). Regarding future
energy prices, since there is much uncertainty on long-term forecasts for the
energy sector, a range of mid-term fossil fuel price scenarios could be used to
assess the opportunity cost. Jedoch, future fossil fuel prices heavily depend on
some key political choices, including the climate mitigation policies adopted by
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
l
/
/
e
D
u
G
e
P
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
/
2
2
4
1
5
2
0
5
8
3
9
8
G
e
P
_
A
_
0
0
6
8
8
P
D
.
l
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
7
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
18 (cid:129) Unburnable Fossil Fuels and Climate Finance
governments around the world. Therefore data from a concrete compensation
proposal (the Yasuní-ITT Initiative from Ecuador) provide a useful basis to cal-
culate a rough, but illustrative, estimate of the total opportunity cost of leaving
the unburnable oil and gas in the ground.
In June 2007, the Ecuadorian government launched the Yasuní-ITT Initia-
tiv, a plan to leave oil reserves untapped in an area with outstanding socioen-
vironmental values, the Yasuní National Park and Biosphere Reserve, one of the
most biodiverse regions of the Amazon and home to some of the last Indige-
nous groups living in voluntary isolation (Marx 2013). Ecuador, for US$ 3.6 billion of compensation from the international community, which was to be paid over a period of ten years, agreed to keep 0.85 billion barrels of heavy crude oil (14.7° API) in the soil of the Yasuní National Park and prevent the release of 0.41 GtCO2 into the atmosphere (Larrea and Warnars 2009). A trust fund managed by the United Nations Development Program was established in 2010 to collect these contributions (Pellegrini et al. 2014). In 2013, approxi- mately US$ 0.34 billion had been committed (and only a fraction had actually
been deposited) to the Yasuní-ITT trust fund, and the initiative was cancelled
because of the disappointing level of international donations (Marx 2013).
The US$ 3.6 billion asked by the Ecuadorian government was approxi- mately half of the total royalties that would have been generated by extracting ITT’s crude oil. The revenues were calculated based on the benchmark price of US$ 72.34 per barrel of WTI crude in mid-2007, assuming a joint venture to
extract the oil, a state share of the revenues of 65 Prozent, an initial capital invest-
ment of US$ 3.5 Milliarde, an operating cost of US$ 12.32 pro Barrel, and a trans-
portation cost of US$ 2.60 pro Barrel (Finer et al. 2009; Larrea and Warnars 2009). The Ecuadorian government was willing to accept US$ 4.20 pro Barrel,
oder 50 percent of the expected oil revenues at that time, to keep the Yasuní-ITT
oil reserves underground (Larrea and Warnars 2009). We use this figure (d.h.,
US$ 4.20 pro Barrel) as the basis of our estimate of global compensation. Since more than 736 gigabarrels (Gbl) of oil and 92 cubic terameters (Tm3) of gas currently classified as reserves should remain unburned to limit global warming to 1.5°C ( Welsby et al. 2021), about US$ 5,400 Milliarde
(109) would be required to compensate the rights holders of oil and gas reserves
(siehe Tabelle 1). Darüber hinaus, new unproven reserves are being and will be discovered
and developed. Global oil and gas nonreserves resource estimates are 3,336 Gbl
of oil and 625 Tm3 of gas (Welsby et al. 2021). Außerdem, coal reserves and
resources estimates are 826 Gt and 3,960 Gt, jeweils (Welsby et al. 2021).
Somit, even the already impressive figure of US$ 5,400 billion is likely to be an underestimation of the opportunity cost for constructing an effective global supply-side climate mitigation policy. Several uncertainties are associated with these calculations (d.h., estimates of fossil fuel reserves and resources, long-term forecasts of energy prices, adoption of demand-side climate mitigation policies, the compensation value at US$ 4.20 pro Barrel, the equivalence of compensa-
tion between oil and gas reserves based on Barrel Oil Equivalents -BOE-, usw.).
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
l
/
/
e
D
u
G
e
P
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
/
2
2
4
1
5
2
0
5
8
3
9
8
G
e
P
_
A
_
0
0
6
8
8
P
D
.
l
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
7
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
Tisch 1
Cost of Compensation for Unburnable Fuels
Burnable
Unburnable
Volumen
Percentage
GBOE
Volumen
Percentage
GBOE
Compensation cost
(billion US$) Reserves Oil (Gbl) Gas (Tm3) Total Resources Oil (Gbl) Gas (Tm3) Total 539 64 783 102 42 41 19 14 539 376 915 783 599 1,381 744 92 3,336 625 58 59 81 86 744 541 1,285 3,336 3,679 7,015 3,125 2,274 5,399 14,011 15,450 29,462 Authors’ elaboration based on Welsby et al. (2021; vgl. Laherrère et al. 2022). To estimate the compensation cost, we multiply the compensation value (d.h., US$ 4.20/barrel) for the global oil and gas reserves (as defined by Welsby et al. 2021) in BOE. Conversion factors used from the US Geological Survey:
6,000 cubic feet of gas equals 1 BOE. Coal has been excluded from the calculations because the attempts to phase out coal consumption have so far
followed a different (and arguably more effective) path than they have for oil and gas.
M
.
Ö
R
T
A
–
M
A
R
T
í
N
e
z
,
L
.
P
e
l
l
e
G
R
ich
N
ich
,
M
.
A
R
S
e
l
,
C
.
M
e
N
A
,
A
N
D
G
.
M
u
ñ
Ö
A
(cid:129)
1
9
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
l
/
/
e
D
u
G
e
P
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
/
2
2
4
1
5
2
0
5
8
3
9
8
G
e
P
_
A
_
0
0
6
8
8
P
D
.
l
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
7
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
20 (cid:129) Unburnable Fossil Fuels and Climate Finance
As a consequence, our figures are meant to be illustrative of the financial chal-
lenges ahead.
Several conundrums remain to be solved to make an agreement on com-
pensation viable. Following the example of the Yasuní-ITT Initiative, and con-
sidering that the remaining budget for 1.5°C warming could be completely
exhausted by 2030, the compensation disbursements could take place on
a yearly basis over the course of ten years (d.h., US$ 540 billion per year). Jedoch, different schedules could be devised to increase the feasibility of the initiative, in terms of being able both to raise the necessary funds and to entice rights holders to join it. Darüber hinaus, given the interdependence of reserves, regulation, and compensation, it would be appropriate for an agreement to compensate forgone production to foresee a benchmark in terms of total reserves available for each party. Zusätzlich, arbitration clauses would also allow enforcing the commitments made and recouping of compensation expenses in case rights holders would renege on their commitments. The Cost of Unburnable Fossil Fuels and Climate Finance To discuss the feasibility and strategies to mobilize the required financial resources, it is productive to put these resources in the context of some recent experience with climate finance. The Green Climate Fund (GCF), the United Nations’ financial mechanism to assist developing countries in climate adapta- tion and mitigation practices, zum Beispiel, has had very limited success. The GCF, set up at the COP 16 In 2010, has so far managed to raise only US$ 18
billion between 2010 Und 2022 (Green Climate Fund 2022).
By far the most realistic approach might be to levy a tax on oil production
and/or exports, epitomized by the Daly–Correa tax (Martínez-Alier et al. 2009).
To this date, this remains the most ambitious international proposal to raise
substantial amounts of funds to support climate action. The tax was first
mooted by Herman Daly in a speech to the Organization of Petroleum Export-
ing Countries (OPEC) In 2001 and tabled by the then president of Ecuador
Rafael Correa at the III Summit of OPEC in 2007 (Martínez-Alier et al. 2009).
The Daly–Correa tax proposal suggested levying on every oil barrel the cost of
the CO2 emission rights from burning a barrel of petroleum. According to the
United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean,
the Daly–Correa tax could generate between US$ 11 billion and 130 billion per year between 2020 Und 2030, depending on the tax rate (aus 1.5% Zu 10%), oil price, and the forecast oil production per year (Antón 2017). The rents collected were proposed to be used to promote sustainable development in low- and middle-income countries, mainly to assist adaptation and mitigation strat- egies for climate change and develop renewable energies. Außerdem, OPEC’s oil exports account for an important share of the total petroleum traded world- wide, attenuating the opportunity for other producers to increase supply by becoming more competitive, and OPEC’s actions influence international oil l D o w n o a d e d f r o m h t t p : / / Direkte . m i t . l / / e d u g e p a r t i c e – p d l f / / / / / 2 2 4 1 5 2 0 5 8 3 9 8 g e p _ a _ 0 0 6 8 8 p d . l f b y g u e s t t o n 0 7 S e p e m b e r 2 0 2 3 M. Orta-Martínez, L. Pellegrini, M. Arsel, C. Mena, and G. Muñoa (cid:129) 21 Preise. OPEC could also act as a fiduciary authority for distributing those rents in the interest of sustainable development, but it was also suggested that these rents could be channeled to the GCF (Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries 2011). While the Daly–Correa tax was not established, the idea of taxing oil pro- duction and export continues to have traction in policy debates. Tatsächlich, a carbon tax to help developing countries adapt to climate change and prevent defores- tation has been implemented by Norway since 2007. Norway’s International Climate and Forest Initiative was launched at the COP 13 In 2008, and since then, it has allocated US$ 0.3 billion annually from Norway’s carbon tax on
offshore oil companies for climate change mitigation, renewable energy, food
security, and conversion to low-carbon energy sources in developing countries
(Røttereng 2018). More recently, the formation of a voluntary “Oil and Climate
Club” has been proposed (Antón 2020). Club members that are oil exporters
would set a tax on their own oil exports, and oil-importing members would tax
oil imports from nonmember countries. A US$ 5 tax per barrel on only 25 pro- cent of global oil exports would result in US$ 18–32 billion annual total reve-
nue (Antón 2020).
These policy proposals, which are insufficient to secure full compensation,
are likely to face significant opposition, as has been the case with initiatives to
establish a global carbon tax that never came to fruition. Ähnlich, the recent US
climate legislation, which includes nearly US$ 370 billion in climate and clean energy investments, contains no carbon taxes (Rhodium Group 2022). Tatsächlich, supply-side climate action is likely to face opposition by fossil fuel interests and by other parties negatively affected by the induced scarcity of fossil fuels. The construction of coalitions supporting supply-side climate policies, including taxation at extraction or export points, is an urgent and challenging task for social movements, concerned citizens, academics, and politicians. Unburnable Fuels, Unrealistic Expectations? As the climate finance record suggests, the burden of raising US$ 5,400 Milliarde
to compensate rights holders forgoing their rights to extract oil and gas seems
insurmountable at first blush. Außerdem, some authors have suggested that
part of what needs to be earmarked as unburnable fuel resources will be left
untapped even in the absence of the impetus of a compensation mechanism
because of already ongoing investment in low-carbon technologies and chang-
ing social preferences (Ansar et al. 2013; Mercure et al. 2018). Ähnlich, the bur-
geoning environmental justice social movement focused on constraining fossil
fuel supply (“Keep It in the Ground”) and the fossil fuel divestment campaigns
have been argued to play a role in effectively curbing fossil fuel production
(Ayling and Gunningham 2015; Piggot 2018). Daher, to fully compensate
owners of unburnable fuels might not only be an implausible solution to limit
global warming but also a non-cost-effective one. Climate action might get
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
l
/
/
e
D
u
G
e
P
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
/
2
2
4
1
5
2
0
5
8
3
9
8
G
e
P
_
A
_
0
0
6
8
8
P
D
.
l
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
7
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
22 (cid:129) Unburnable Fossil Fuels and Climate Finance
better or least-cost results allocating climate funds to increase investment in
alternative energy sources or applying alternative demand and supply-side pol-
icies (z.B., credit restrictions to fossil fuel exploration and extraction activities,
degrowth). Außerdem, investment in alternative energy sources is key to
securing future energy demands if fossil fuels need to be phased out. Jedoch,
given the urgency and magnitude of the challenge of climate change, an “either–
or” approach between unburnable fuels and investing in alternative visions and
technologies might be shortsighted. Climate action might not aim at the full
compensation for resource owners to effectively curb fossil fuel production.
Trotzdem, to compensate owners of those specific reserves that overlap with
highly biodiverse regions and/or coincide with outstanding socioenvironmental
Werte (Harfoot et al. 2018) might be instrumental to protecting these areas
from imminent threat, guiding divestment strategies to maximize the collateral
benefits of climate policies. Darüber hinaus, while compensation might be needed to
overcome the resistance of fossil fuel interests in these specific reserves, climate
ethics principles could be followed to prioritize compensation based on depen-
dence on fossil fuel (d.h., on the social costs of transitioning to renewables)
and the capability to face these costs at the country level. Thus compensation
would be needed only for developing countries whose economies depend on
fossil fuels.
Letzten Endes, as the impacts of climate change become increasingly mani-
fest, a “whatever it takes” approach, guided by Keynes’ famous dictum (welche
referred to high-quality public and private projects) that “anything we can actu-
ally do we can afford,” might gain traction in the global public sphere (Keynes
2012, 270). Lest this seem unrealistic, it is worth recalling the (ongoing) efforts
to respond to the COVID-19 pandemic. The stimulus package of the European
Union, “Recovery Plan Europe,” exceeds the A2,000 billion for the 2021–2027
budgeting period, not including the financial packages put together by individ-
ual member countries (European Commission 2022). Ähnlich, the United
States passed multi-trillion-dollar stimulus packages—with the single Coronavi-
rus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security (CARES) Act estimated at US$ 2,300 bil- lion (US Department of the Treasury 2022). At the level of intergovernmental organizations, the International Monetary Fund allocated approximately US$ 650 billion of special drawing rights to member countries (International
Monetary Fund 2021).
The resources raised in response to the COVID-19 pandemic ultimately
show that the main shortcoming in mobilizing seemingly impossible sums is
the availability of political will rather than financial resources. As the gravity
of the latest Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change report’s warning that
“any further delay in concerted anticipatory action on adaptation and mitiga-
tion will miss a brief and rapidly closing window of opportunity to secure a
livable and sustainable future for all” (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
Change, bevorstehend) becomes internalized by policy makers and citizens
auf der ganzen Welt, a global initiative to leave a substantial portion of fossil fuel
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
l
/
/
e
D
u
G
e
P
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
/
2
2
4
1
5
2
0
5
8
3
9
8
G
e
P
_
A
_
0
0
6
8
8
P
D
.
l
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
7
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
M. Orta-Martínez, L. Pellegrini, M. Arsel, C. Mena, and G. Muñoa
(cid:129) 23
resources under the ground with partial compensation for rights holders to dras-
tically reduce emissions before 2030 might become more feasible (van Asselt
and Newell, this issue). Jedoch, major political challenges remain, einschließlich
hurdles in international diplomacy and cooperation (z.B., differentiated respon-
sibilities, confidence and credibility of the governing multilateral institution,
enforcement mechanisms) to come to an agreement as well as the imperatives
to increase investment in alternative energy sources and improve technology
transfer to meet global energy demand.
Martí Orta-Martínez is a research professor of environmental sciences and biol-
ogy at the Department of Evolutionary Biology, Ecology, and Environmental
Wissenschaften, University of Barcelona. He has developed a research career on envi-
ronmental forensics and political ecology of extractive industries in tropical
rainforests and Indigenous territories of remote areas of the world. He has
almost twenty years of experience working on socioenvironmental conflicts
and environmental health and pollution from the upstream oil industry in
the Amazon, Central Africa, and Siberia. Some of his most recent and relevant
publications include “First Evidences of Amazonian Wildlife Feeding on
Petroleum-Contaminated Soils: A New Exposure Route to Petrogenic Com-
pounds?” ““The squeaky wheel gets the grease”? The conflict imperative and
the slow fight against environmental injustice in northern Peruvian Amazon”
and “Institutional Mechanisms to Keep Unburnable Fossil Fuel Reserves in
the Soil.”
Lorenzo Pellegrini’s research interests include the socioenvironmental impact
of extractive industries, environmental justice, climate change, impact evalua-
tion, institutions, and corruption. Recent publications include articles on the
Texaco/Chevron case, the resource curse, the global extractive imperative, Und
conservation and conflict in DRC. Professor Pellegrini has led and participated
in a number of research projects in collaboration with researchers and social
movements in the Global South. He teaches courses on research methodology,
development economics, development theory, nachhaltige Entwicklung, Und
ecological economics.
Murat Arsel is a professor of political economy at the International Institute of
Social Studies, Erasmus University Rotterdam. The overall focus of his research
is on the relationship between capitalism, nature, and society. He is currently
working on several different strands of research, including unburnable fuels,
infrastructure and authoritarian developmentalism, and climate conflicts in
cities at the front lines of sea level rise, such as Jakarta and Miami.
Carlos F. Mena is a professor of geography at the School of Biological and Envi-
ronmental Sciences in the Universidad San Francisco de Quito, Ecuador. Mena
is codirector of the Galapagos Science Center and director of the Institute of
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
l
/
/
e
D
u
G
e
P
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
/
2
2
4
1
5
2
0
5
8
3
9
8
G
e
P
_
A
_
0
0
6
8
8
P
D
.
l
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
7
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
24 (cid:129) Unburnable Fossil Fuels and Climate Finance
Geography at USFQ. Mena obtained his PhD in geography from the University
of North Carolina at Chapel Hill and worked in the Ecuadorian Amazon for
several years for his dissertation research. Currently Mena develops projects ana-
lyzing the interactions between human and environment using GIS, remote
sensing, social survey, and political ecology in the Western Amazon and the
Galápagos Islands.
Gorka Muñoa holds a PhD in environmental sciences (Institute of Environmen-
tal Science and Technology, Autonomous University of Barcelona; ICTA-UAB), A
MSc in geographic information systems and remote sensing (Institute of Space
Sciences of Catalonia), and a MSc in interdisciplinary studies in environmental,
wirtschaftlich, and social sustainability (ICTA-UAB). His main interests are in the
remote sensing of oil spills, forest disturbance, and deforestation from extractive
industries in tropical rainforest as well as the unburnable fossil fuels and climate
change mitigation policies. He has recently published “Institutional Mecha-
nisms to Keep Unburnable Fossil Fuel Reserves in the Soil,” Energy Policy 149.
Verweise
Ansar, A., B. Caldecott, and J. Tilbury. 2013. Stranded Assets and the Fossil Fuel Divestment
Campaign: What Does Divestment Mean for the Valuation of Fossil Fuel Assets? Oxford,
Vereinigtes Königreich: School of Enterprise and the Environment, Universität Oxford.
Antón, A. 2017. El impuesto Daly-Correa: Estimaciones preliminares sobre su potencial recau-
datorio. Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEPAL),
United Nations. https://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/40940-impuesto-daly
-correa-estimaciones-preliminares-su-potencial-recaudatorio.
Antón, A. 2020. Taxing Crude Oil: A Financing Alternative to Mitigate Climate Change?
Energy Policy 136: 111031. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2019.111031
Ayling, J., and N. Gunningham. 2015. Non-state Governance and Climate Policy: Der
Fossil Fuel Divestment Movement. Climate Policy 17 (2): 131–149. https://doi
.org/10.1080/14693062.2015.1094729
Busby, C., B. Dachis, and B. Dahlby. 2011. Rethinking Royalty Rates: Why There Is a
Better Way to Tax Oil and Gas Development. C.D. Howe Institute 333: 36.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1943694
Erickson, P., M. Lazarus, and G. Piggot. 2018. Limiting Fossil Fuel Production as the Next
Big Step in Climate Policy. Nature Climate Change 8 (12): 1037–1043. https://doi
.org/10.1038/s41558-018-0337-0
European Commission. 2022. Recovery Plan for Europe. Brussels, Belgien: European
Commission.
Finer, M., R. Moncel, and C. N. Jenkins. 2009. Leaving the Oil Under the Amazon:
Ecuador’s Yasuní-ITT Initiative. Biotropica 42 (1): 63–66. https://doi.org/10.1111
/j.1744-7429.2009.00587.x
Global Gas and Oil Network. 2019. Oil, Gas and the Climate: An Analysis of Oil and Gas
Industry Plans for Expansion and Compatibility with Global Emission Limits. Sugar Land,
TX: Global Gas and Oil Network.
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
l
/
/
e
D
u
G
e
P
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
/
2
2
4
1
5
2
0
5
8
3
9
8
G
e
P
_
A
_
0
0
6
8
8
P
D
.
l
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
7
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
M. Orta-Martínez, L. Pellegrini, M. Arsel, C. Mena, and G. Muñoa
(cid:129) 25
Grün, F., and D. Kuch. 2022. Counting Carbon or Counting Coal? Anchoring Climate
Governance in Fossil Fuel–Based Accountability Frameworks. Global Environmental
Politik 22 (4): 48–69. https://doi.org/10.1162/glep_a_00654
Green Climate Fund. 2022. Status of Pledges and Contributions Made to the Green
Climate Fund. Verfügbar um: https://www.greenclimate.fund/document/status
-pledges-and-contributions-initial-resource-mobilization, last accessed September
16, 2022.
Harfoot, M. B. J., D. P. Tittensor, S. Ritter, A. P. Arnell, S. Blyth, S. Brooks, S. H. M.
Butchart, J. Hutton, M. ICH. Jones, V. Kapos, J. P. W. Scharlemann, and N. D. Bürger.
2018. Present and Future Biodiversity Risks from Fossil Fuel Exploitation. Conser-
vation Letters 11 (4): e12448. https://doi.org/10.1111/conl.12448
Höhne, N., M. den Elzen, J. Rogelj, B. Metz, T. Fransen, T. Kuramochi, A. Olhoff, J. Alcamo, H.
Winkler, S. Fu, M. Schäffer, R. Schäffer, G. P. Peters, S. Maxwell, and N. K. Dubash.
2020. Emissions: World Has Four Times the Work or One-Third of the Time. Natur
579 (7797): 25–28. https://doi.org/10.1038/d41586-020-00571-x, PubMed: 32132686
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Demnächst. Climate Change 2022:
Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Working Group II. Contribution to the Sixth
Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge,
Vereinigtes Königreich: Cambridge University Press.
International Energy Agency. 2021. Net Zero by 2050: A Roadmap for the Global Energy Sector.
Paris, Frankreich: International Energy Agency. https://doi.org/10.1787/c8328405-en
International Monetary Fund. 2021. Guidance Note for Fund Staff on the Treatment and
Use of SDR Allocations. Publication 2021/059. Washington, Gleichstrom: International
Monetary Fund. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781513593340.007
Jakob, M., and J. Hilaire. 2015. Fossil-Fuel Reserves. Natur 517: 150–152. https://doi.org
/10.1038/517150A, PubMed: 25567276
Kartha, S., S. Caney, N. K. Dubash, and G. Muttitt. 2018. Whose Carbon Is Burnable?
Equity Considerations in the Allocation of a “Right to Extract.” Climatic Change
150 (1–2): 117–129. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-018-2209-z
Keynes, John Maynard. 2012. The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Bd. XXVII.
2nd ed. London, Vereinigtes Königreich: Royal Economic Society.
Laherrère, J., C. A. S. Hall, and R. Bentley. 2022. How Much Oil Remains for the World to
Produce? Comparing Assessment Methods, and Separating Fact from Fiction.
Current Research in Environmental Sustainability 4: 100174. https://doi.org/10
.1016/j.crsust.2022.100174
Larrea, C., and L. Warnars. 2009. Ecuador’s Yasuni-ITT Initiative: Avoiding Emissions
by Keeping Petroleum Underground. Energy for Sustainable Development 13 (3):
219–223. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.esd.2009.08.003
Lazarus, M., and H. van Asselt. 2018. Fossil Fuel Supply and Climate Policy: Exploring
the Road Less Taken. Climatic Change 150 (1–2): 1–13. https://doi.org/10.1007
/s10584-018-2266-3
Lenton, T. M., J. Rockström, Ö. Gaffney, S. Rahmstorf, K. Richardson, W. Steffen, Und
H. J. Schellnhuber. 2019. Climate Tipping Points—Too Risky to Bet Against.
Natur 575 (7784): 592–595. https://doi.org/10.1038/d41586-019-03595-0,
PubMed: 31776487
Martínez-Alier, Joan. 2022. Circularity, Entropy, Ecological Conflicts and LFFU. Lokal
Umfeld 27 (10–11): 1182–1207. https://doi.org/10.1080/13549839.2021
.1983795
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
l
/
/
e
D
u
G
e
P
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
/
2
2
4
1
5
2
0
5
8
3
9
8
G
e
P
_
A
_
0
0
6
8
8
P
D
.
l
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
7
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
26 (cid:129) Unburnable Fossil Fuels and Climate Finance
Martínez-Alier, J., F. Schneider, F. Mestrum, S. Giljum, and R. Weiler. 2009. Sozial
Sustainable Economic Degrowth. In Proceedings of a Workshop in the European Par-
liament on April 16, 2009, edited by T. Schauer. Rome, Italien: Club of
Rome/European Support Centre.
Marx, E. 2013. Ecuador Says It Will Launch Controversial Drilling in Amazon Park.
Wissenschaft, August 19.
Matthews, H. D., K. B. Tokarska, J. Rogelj, C. J. Schmied, A. H. MacDougall, K. Haustein, N.
Mengis, S. Sippel, P. M. Forster, and R. Knutti. 2021. An Integrated Approach to
Quantifying Uncertainties in the Remaining Carbon Budget. Communications Earth
and Environment 2 (1): 7. https://doi.org/10.1038/s43247-020-00064-9
McGlade, C., and P. Ekins. 2015. The Geographical Distribution of Fossil Fuels Unused
When Limiting Global Warming to 2°C. Natur 517 (7533): 187–190. https://doi
.org/10.1038/nature14016, PubMed: 25567285
Meinshausen, M., N. Meinshausen, W. Hare, S. C. B. Raper, K. Frieler, R. Knutti, D. J.
Frame, and M. R. Allen. 2009. Greenhouse-Gas Emission Targets for Limiting
Global Warming to 2°C. Natur 458 (7242): 1158–1162. https://doi.org/10
.1038/nature08017, PubMed: 19407799
Mercure, J. F., H. Pollitt, J. E. Viñuales, N. R. Edwards, P. B. Holden, U. Chewpreecha, P.
Salas, ICH. Sognnaes, A. Lam, and F. Knobloch. 2018. Macroeconomic Impact of
Stranded Fossil Fuel Assets. Nature Climate Change 8 (7): 588–593. https://doi
.org/10.1038/s41558-018-0182-1
Muttitt, G., and S. Kartha. 2020. Equity, Climate Justice and Fossil Fuel Extraction: Prin-
ciples for a Managed Phase Out. Climate Policy 20 (8): 1024–1042. https://doi.org
/10.1080/14693062.2020.1763900
Natural Resource Governance Institute. 2019. The National Oil Company Database. Neu
York, New York: Natural Resource Governance Institute.
Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries. 2011. Ecuador’s President Confident
OPEC Can Offer Effective Solutions to Global Challenges. OPEC Bulletin 42 (1):
16–21.
Pellegrini, L., and M. Arsel. (2022). The Supply-Side of Climate Policies: Keeping
Unburnable Fossil Fuels in the Ground. Globale Umweltpolitik 22 (4): 1–14.
https://doi.org/10.1162/glep_a_00691
Pellegrini, L., M. Arsel, F. Falconí, and R. Muradian. 2014. The Demise of a New Conser-
vation and Development Policy? Exploring the Tensions of the Yasuní ITT Initia-
tiv. Extractive Industries and Society 1 (2): 284–291. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.exis
.2014.05.001
Pellegrini, L., M. Arsel, M. Orta-Martínez, C. F. Mena, and G. Muñoa. 2021. Institutional
Mechanisms to Keep Unburnable Fossil Fuel Reserves in the Soil. Energy Policy 149:
112029. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2020.112029
Piggot, G. 2018. The Influence of Social Movements on Policies That Constrain Fossil
Fuel Supply. Climate Policy 18 (7): 942–954. https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062
.2017.1394255
Piggot, G., C. Verkuijl, H. van Asselt, and M. Lazarus. 2020. Curbing Fossil Fuel Supply to
Achieve Climate Goals. Climate Policy 20 (8): 881–887. https://doi.org/10.1080
/14693062.2020.1804315
Pye, S., S. Bradley, N. Hughes, J. Price, D. Welsby, and P. Ekins. 2020. An Equitable Redis-
tribution of Unburnable Carbon. Nature Communications 11 (1): 1–9. https://doi
.org/10.1038/s41467-020-17679-3, PubMed: 32770062
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
l
/
/
e
D
u
G
e
P
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
/
2
2
4
1
5
2
0
5
8
3
9
8
G
e
P
_
A
_
0
0
6
8
8
P
D
.
l
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
7
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
M. Orta-Martínez, L. Pellegrini, M. Arsel, C. Mena, and G. Muñoa
(cid:129) 27
Rhodium Group. 2022. A Turning Point for US Climate Progress: Assessing the Climate
and Clean Energy Provisions in the Inflation Reduction Act. Verfügbar um: https://
rhg.com/research/climate-clean-energy-inflation-reduction-act/, last accessed
September 16, 2022.
Røttereng, J. K. S. 2018. When Climate Policy Meets Foreign Policy: Pioneering and
National Interest in Norway’s Mitigation Strategy. Energy Research and Social Science
39: 216–225. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.erss.2017.11.024
Rystad Energy. 2020. Global Oil Production Costs Continue to Fall. Verfügbar um: https://
oilprice.com/ Energy/Crude-Oil/Global-Oil-Production-Costs-Continue-To-Fall
.html, last accessed September 16, 2022.
US Department of the Treasury. 2022. COVID-19 Economic Relief. Verfügbar um: https://
home.treasury.gov/policy-issues/coronavirus, last accessed September 16, 2022.
Welsby, D., J. Price, S. Pye, and P. Ekins. 2021. Unextractable Fossil Fuels in a 1.5°C
Welt. Natur 597: 230–234. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41586-021-03821-8,
PubMed: 34497394
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
l
/
/
e
D
u
G
e
P
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
/
2
2
4
1
5
2
0
5
8
3
9
8
G
e
P
_
A
_
0
0
6
8
8
P
D
.
l
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
7
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
PDF Herunterladen