The Labor Productivity Gap between the
Agricultural and Nonagricultural Sectors, Und
Poverty and Inequality Reduction in Asia
Katsushi Imai, Raghav Gaiha, and Fabrizio Bresciani∗
The objective of this paper is to examine how agricultural and nonagricultural
labor productivities have grown over time and whether the growth pattern
affected poverty in low- and middle-income economies in Asia. We first
examine whether labor productivities in the agricultural and nonagricultural
sectors have converged, finding evidence that they did not as the latter have
grown faster. We then confirm that both agricultural and nonagricultural labor
productivities have converged across economies and that the convergence effect
is stronger for the nonagricultural sector. We have also observed that, despite
the relatively slower growth in agricultural labor productivity, the agricultural
sector played an important role in promoting nonagricultural labor productivity
and thus in nonagricultural growth. Endlich, we have found some evidence
that the labor productivity gap reduces rural and urban poverty, sowie
national-level inequality.
Schlüsselwörter: agricultural labor productivity, Asien, inequality, labor productivity
gap, Armut
JEL-Codes: C23, I32, J24, O13
ICH. Einführung
The objective of this paper is to examine (ich) how labor productivities in
the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors in Asia have grown over time, Und (ii)
whether the growth pattern—proxied by the labor productivity gap between the two
sectors—affected poverty and inequality in low- and middle-income economies
in Asien. We focus on these economies because the interaction between the
agricultural and nonagricultural sectors has become increasingly important as these
∗Katsushi Imai (Korrespondierender Autor): Associate Professor, Department of Economics, School of Social Sciences,
University of Manchester, Großbritannien. Email: Katsushi.Imai@manchester.ac.uk; Raghav Gaiha: Honorary
Professorial Research Fellow, Global Development Institute, University of Manchester, United Kingdom and Visiting
Scholar, Population Studies Centre, University of Pennsylvania, Vereinigte Staaten; Fabrizio Bresciani: Lead Economist,
Asia and the Pacific Division, International Fund for Agricultural Development, Italien. Email: f.bresciani@ifad.org.
This study is funded by the Asia and the Pacific Division of the International Fund for Agricultural Development.
The opinions expressed in this publication are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the
International Fund for Agricultural Development. The authors would like to thank the managing editor and three
anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions. The usual ADB disclaimer applies.
Asiatischer Entwicklungsbericht, Bd. 36, NEIN. 1, S. 112–135
https://doi.org/10.1162/adev_a_00125
© 2019 Asian Development Bank and
Asian Development Bank Institute.
Veröffentlicht unter Creative Commons
Namensnennung 3.0 International (CC BY 3.0) Lizenz.
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
/
.
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 113
economies have experienced structural transformation. We will first investigate the
convergence of labor productivity in the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors
with a focus on both intersectoral convergence and within-sector convergence
across different economies over time.
The issue of intersectoral convergence versus divergence is reviewed in
the literature, which investigates allocations or misallocations of inputs into the
agricultural and nonagricultural sectors. Zum Beispiel, using microlevel data, Gollin,
Lagakos, and Waugh (2013) found that a large gap between the two sectors persists,
suggesting the misallocation of labor at the macro level. Jedoch, the extent of
the gap and how it has changed over time differs across economies depending on
their initial capital and labor endowments, the stage of economic development, Und
the nature of their public policies. As the degree of the misallocation of resources
in dual-economy settings explains variations in national income and productivity
Wachstum (Vollrath 2009), it is important to examine how the gap has changed over
Zeit.
To investigate whether the growth pattern impacts poverty and inequality
in low- and middle-income economies in Asia, we draw upon the large empirical
literature to test the convergence hypothesis in line with the neoclassical growth
Modell: das ist, whether poorer economies or regions grow faster than richer
economies or regions (Barro 1991, Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1992, Barro et al.
1991). Zum Beispiel, Barro et al. (1991) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992) gebraucht
state-level data on personal income for 48 states in the United States (US) während
1940–1963 and found clear evidence of convergence. As for convergence across
economies, while the earlier literature suggests that there was convergence across
a wide range of economies (Barro [1991] observes 98 economies during 1960–
1985) and that the convergence was also observed for productivity growth (Baumol,
Nelson, and Wolff 1994), it has been debated whether the convergence occurred
for a subset of economies or for different specifications (Levine and Renelt 1992,
Quah 1996). The results partly depend on the extent to which the economies are
integrated, zum Beispiel, through international trade (Ben-David 1996). Given that
East and South Asian economies are becoming more integrated, an interesting
question is whether productivity converged among Asian economies.
We will also investigate whether the gap is associated with poverty and
inequality reduction in rural and urban areas. While the literature has focused on the
poverty-reducing effect of agricultural sector income or productivity growth, little is
known about whether the gap between agricultural and nonagricultural productivity
influences poverty or inequality.1 A point of departure is that we treat the labor
productivity gap as endogenous by using the fixed-effects instrumental-variable
(FE-IV) Modell, where the cropping pattern is used as an instrument. Endlich, Wir
1See Imai, Gaiha, and Bresciani (2016) for the evidence for Asia.
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
.
/
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
114 Asiatischer Entwicklungsbericht
will discuss whether the labor productivity gap will dynamically affect the labor
allocation between rural and urban sectors.
Our paper draws upon the following three strands of the literature. Der Erste
is the literature on the empirical investigations of the gap between agricultural
and nonagricultural productivities in the dual-economy model, consisting of the
traditional and modern sectors. A seminal work in this strand of the literature
is Gollin, Lagakos, and Waugh (2013), who used both national accounts and
household data to show that value added per worker is much higher in the
nonagricultural than agricultural sector in developing economies. They call this
the “agricultural productivity gap.” As Gollin, Lagakos, and Waugh (2013, P. 942)
Notiz, the investigation of the agricultural productivity gap has been viewed as an
important topic in the early literature on development economics as it can offer
valuable insights into the analysis of economic growth and inequality in developing
economies (z.B., Lewis 1955, Kuznets 1971). In den vergangenen Jahren, the agricultural and
nonagricultural sectors have become more integrated within economies through
structural transformation, while the agricultural (or nonagricultural) sector of one
economy has become more closely linked with the same sector of other economies
under globalization. Given the nature of the data that Gollin, Lagakos, and Waugh
(2013) gebraucht, their analysis is essentially static. Jedoch, it is important to analyze
the gap in a dynamic context. Drawing upon the panel data of Asian economies, Die
present study focuses on how agricultural and nonagricultural labor productivities
have grown, with their interactions taken into account. It also estimates the effect of
the gap on poverty and inequality.
Zweite, our study is closely related to the large body of the literature on
the role of the agricultural sector in development and the reduction of poverty and
inequality (z.B., Christiaensen, Demery, and Kuhl 2011). A point of departure of the
recent literature (Christiaensen, Demery, and Kuhl 2011; Imai, Cheng, and Gaiha
2017) is that the role of agriculture is captured by dynamic interactions between the
agriculture and nonagricultural sectors. The present study extends these arguments
and focuses on the effect of the labor productivity gap between the two sectors on
poverty and inequality.
Dritte, the present study is also closely related to the literature on structural
transformation, in particular rural transformation (or agricultural transformation),
and its effect on development and/or poverty in low- and middle-income economies
in Asia and elsewhere (z.B., Reardon and Timmer 2014, Dawe 2015, Barrett
et al. 2017). As the structural transformation implies a closer and more intricate
relationship between the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors, our empirical
investigation of the gap between agricultural and nonagricultural productivity can
provide useful insight into the literature on structural transformation.
Der Rest der Arbeit ist wie folgt gegliedert. In the next section, we briefly
summarize the theoretical foundations underlying our empirical investigation. In
section III, we examine the convergence of labor productivity in the agricultural and
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
/
.
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 115
nonagricultural sectors. Section IV estimates the effects of the labor productivity
gap on poverty, inequality, and the sectoral population share. The final section offers
our concluding observations.
II. Theoretical Foundations
Unser
empirical
investigation of
the gap between agricultural
Und
nonagricultural labor productivity is associated with a large body of theoretical
literature on the dual-economy model, which originated from Arthur Lewis (1954)
and was later developed by many authors (z.B., Dixit 1973, Mundlak 2000).
More recently, Vollrath (2009) constructs a dual-economy model in which the
productivity differences between the two sectors arise endogenously. In Vollrath’s
Modell, agricultural production is a constant returns to scale function of labor effort
and land (Vollrath 2009, P. 8). Total agricultural production is denoted as
Y A
T
= AA
t F
(cid:3)
(cid:2)
R, EA
T
(1)
where Y A
is agricultural production at time t (and superscript A denotes the
T
agricultural sector), AA
is total factor productivity of the agricultural sector, R is
T
the total amount of land (or resources in general) in the agricultural sector, Und
= statLt. F is a well-behaved function with
EA
T
constant returns to scale. Net income for a representative farmer in the agricultural
sector is
is the total labor effort: das ist, EA
T
I A
T
= pA
t AA
t F (rt,st ) − ρtrt
(2)
where rt is the land employed by the farmer at time t. Each individual has a unit
of time, with the share st ∈ (0, 1) allocated to productive work in the agricultural
sector and the remaining 1 − st spent in nonfarm activity at time t. ρt is the rental
price of land, and pA
is the price of agricultural goods relative to manufactured
T
goods.
The manufacturing (nonagricultural) sector is assumed to be perfectly
competitive so that labor effort is paid its marginal product (Vollrath 2009, P. 9).
The wage rate per unit of effort in the nonagricultural sector is specified as
wM
T
= AM
T
w (bei )
(3)
where the wage rate depends on the productivity of nonagricultural sector, BIN
,
T
as well as on a well-behaved function w of the number of people in agriculture,
bei (w(cid:4) > 0 and w(cid:4)(cid:4) > 0), given the assumption that the nonagricultural sector is
competitive, while the agricultural sector is not. These properties imply that the
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
/
.
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
116 Asiatischer Entwicklungsbericht
nonagricultural wage increases as the number of people in the nonagricultural sector
(1 − at ) decreases. Net income for nonagricultural workers is simply defined by
I M
T
= wM
t st
(4)
Under these settings, Vollrath (2009, P. 11) showed that in equilibrium a dual
economy exists where nonagricultural workers allocate more time to productive
work than agricultural workers, and the marginal product of a worker is higher
for nonagricultural (manufacturing) workers.2 As a result, gross domestic product
(BIP) per capita can be increased by a transfer of labor from the agricultural
sector to the nonagricultural sector. Vollrath’s model (2009, P. 13) also implies that
sustained increases in agricultural productivity will help industrialize the economy,
but this will be accompanied by a growing disparity in productivity between sectors.
Andererseits, increases in nonagricultural productivity will not only industrialize
the economy but also induce agricultural workers to work more efficiently.3 This
model prediction is intuitively valid given close interactions between the two sectors
through migration, particularly in emerging economies such as India, the People’s
Republic of China, and Viet Nam.
The above model would predict, in our empirical context, that the gap in labor
productivity between the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors expands as the
economy grows. As the gap in labor productivity between the two sectors implies
an improvement in relative productivity of the nonagricultural sector, it is likely to
reduce poverty. Also, we will test the hypotheses directly related to Vollrath (2009)
Das (ich) the labor productivity gap between the agricultural and nonagricultural
sectors expands over time, Und (ii) the labor productivity gap between the two
sectors reduces poverty. As we will discuss later, our empirical results are broadly
consistent with Vollrath (2009).
Vollrath’s (2009) model also implies that agricultural productivity and
nonagricultural productivity interact in a complicated way. Jedoch, the model does
not explicitly consider the interactions with factors outside the economy. Assuming
the concavity of the production function in both sectors, we will empirically
investigate whether agricultural productivity will converge or not across Asian
economies by taking account of the effect of the lagged nonagricultural productivity
on agricultural productivity. The convergence of nonagricultural productivity will
also be examined by incorporating the effect of agricultural productivity on
nonagricultural productivity. This empirical model is oriented in the literature to
test the convergence of economic growth (Barro 1991, Barro and Sala-i-Martin
1992, Barro et al. 1991).
Vollrath (2009) predicts that in the long term the agricultural sector’s
productivity growth will exacerbate the inefficiencies of a dual economy and
2See Vollrath (2009, S. 8–11) for details on how equations (1)–(4) will lead to the results.
3See Vollrath (2009, S. 12–13 and the Appendix) for more details.
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
.
/
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 117
produce slower overall growth than will nonagricultural sector productivity
Verbesserungen, and therefore the dual economy will disappear. This is consistent
with empirical observations of developed Asian economies such as Japan and the
Republik Korea. While both of these economies improved their agricultural
productivity in the late 20th century, the GDP share of the agricultural sector
declined as they industrialized and eventually achieved higher overall productivity.
In der Zwischenzeit, the overall inequality of these economies remained relatively low
and stable.4 However, Vollrath (2009) lacks two aspects. Erste, the effect of the
persistence of the dual economy on income distribution is not explicitly analyzed.
Zweite, focusing on the long-term effect, Vollrath’s model may not fully capture the
positive role of agriculture on economic growth and the reduction of poverty and
inequality, which is important in most low- and middle-income economies in Asia
wie Indien. Zum Beispiel, Ravallion and Datt (1996) gebraucht 35 household surveys
of India between 1951 Und 1991 and found that the growth of the primary sector
(mainly agriculture) and the tertiary sector (mainly services) reduced national,
ländlich, and urban poverty significantly, while growth of the secondary sector (mainly
manufacturing) increased national poverty. They also showed that rural growth is
more important for poverty reduction than urban growth. It is evident that a separate
theoretical model is necessary to analyze the effect of a dual economy on income
distribution and poverty.
Some authors have explored the relationship between growth and income
distribution with a focus on the dual economy (z.B., Robinson 1976, Bourguignon
1990, Fields 1993, Bourguignon and Morrisson 1998). Bourguignon (1990) offers a
theoretical ground for Kuznets’ hypothesis in detail. The dual economy is modeled
in a general equilibrium framework by taking account of the entire distribution,
which generates a Lorenz curve rather than summary measures. Bourguignon
(1990, P. 219) first derived a proposition that a “necessary and sufficient condition
for growth to shift the Lorenz curve of the income distribution upward is that
the share of the traditional sector in GDP increases with growth.” That is, ein
increase of the share of the agricultural sector in the growth process tends to reduce
inequality. Jedoch, as Bourguignon notes, it is unlikely that the agricultural sector
share increases with growth. Bourguignon (1990, S. 226–27) then derives the
proposition that a “necessary condition for growth to be unambiguously egalitarian,
despite a fall in the GDP share of the traditional sector, is that capital–labor
substitution be inelastic in the modern sector,” implying that “observing a falling
GDP share of the traditional sector, together with elastic capital–labor substitution
in the modern sector, is sufficient to rule out unambiguously egalitarian growth
in a dual economy.” That is, the model predicts that the disparity between the
4The income Gini coefficient of the Republic of Korea declined from 0.34 In 1965 Zu 0.31 In 1993 (Choo
1991) and that of Japan fell from 0.29 In 1966 Zu 0.28 In 1998 (based on the Family Income and Expenditure Survey
from Moriguchi and Saez 2008). Both economies experienced a decline in the GDP share of agriculture during the
respective review period.
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
.
/
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
118 Asiatischer Entwicklungsbericht
agricultural and nonagricultural sectors tends to increase inequality with elastic
capital–labor substitution in the nonagricultural (modern) sector. Bourguignon’s
model motivates our empirical analysis of the relationship between the agricultural–
nonagricultural labor productivity gap and inequality and poverty.
III. Convergence of Labor Productivity in the Agricultural
and Nonagricultural Sectors
Drawing upon the theoretical discussion in the last section, this section
will examine the relationship between agricultural
labor productivity and
nonagricultural labor productivity with a focus on whether (ich) these two converge
or diverge over time, (ii) agricultural labor productivity converges across different
economies, Und (iii) nonagricultural labor productivity converges across different
economies. Für (ii) Und (iii), the intersectoral effects are also taken into account
in one case. Das
labor productivity
on agricultural labor productivity is considered. Für (iii), the effect of lagged
agricultural labor productivity on nonagricultural labor productivity is taken into
account. For simplicity, the labor productivity of the agricultural (nonagricultural)
sector is defined as value added in the agricultural (nonagricultural) sector divided
by the number of workers in the agricultural (nonagricultural) sector.
the effect of lagged nonagricultural
Ist,
Tisch 1 compares labor productivity in these sectors by economy and region,
and for Asia as a whole. The comparison is also made for the entire period as
well as before and after the year 2000. Tisch 1 reports labor productivity growth
as well as the labor productivity gap as defined by the gap between the logarithm of
agricultural value added per worker and the logarithm of value added per worker
in the nonagricultural sector. Consistent with earlier literature (z.B., Martin and
Mitra 2001, Bernard and Jones 1996), nonagricultural labor productivity is higher
in all cases except the Federated States of Micronesia before 2000. Auch, Die
labor productivity gap is higher after 2000 in all cases except Fiji. Our results
strongly confirm the labor productivity divergence between the two sectors. Das ist,
nonagricultural labor productivity was higher than agricultural labor productivity to
start with and that the gap has expanded over time.
the gap has only moderately increased, Aber
Jedoch, there is a great degree of heterogeneity in terms of the speed of
divergence. Zum Beispiel, in a few economies (z.B., Indonesia and the Federated
in other
States of Micronesia),
economies (z.B., Bhutan, Indien, and the People’s Republic of China), the gap
dramatically increased after 2000. It is thus safe to conclude that there is no evidence
of labor productivity convergence between the agricultural and nonagricultural
sectors. This is due to the fact that while agricultural labor productivity has grown
substantially since 2000, nonagricultural labor productivity has grown even faster
in many economies.
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
.
/
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 119
R
Ö
B
A
L
R
Ö
B
A
L
R
Ö
B
A
L
R
Ö
B
A
L
R
Ö
B
A
L
R
Ö
B
A
L
R
Ö
B
A
L
R
Ö
B
A
L
R
Ö
B
A
L
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
C
P
A
G
B
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
A
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
C
P
A
G
B
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
A
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
C
P
A
G
B
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
A
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
0
0
0
2
R
e
T
F
A
0
0
0
2
e
R
Ö
F
e
B
S
R
Ö
T
C
e
S
e
S
e
H
T
N
ich
l
A
T
Ö
T
)
l
e
v
e
l
N
ich
(
P
A
G
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
R
Ö
B
A
L
e
H
T
D
N
A
,
S
R
Ö
T
C
e
S
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
D
N
A
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
e
H
T
N
ich
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
R
Ö
B
A
L
.
1
e
l
B
A
T
9
3
1
.
8
2
1
.
2
5
1
.
1
6
0
.
8
2
1
.
9
9
1
.
4
3
1
.
4
7
0
.
6
0
2
.
2
8
1
.
1
9
1
.
2
6
0
.
2
5
2
.
9
0
1
.
7
9
1
.
8
0
1
.
6
4
1
.
4
3
1
.
2
4
1
.
5
1
5
.
4
1
7
.
7
4
6
.
9
2
2
.
5
1
3
.
7
9
4
.
3
8
4
.
9
9
7
.
5
7
9
.
7
9
0
.
1
5
4
.
8
6
7
.
1
4
3
.
9
1
0
.
4
3
3
.
7
8
4
.
2
0
6
.
4
6
4
.
6
1
5
.
7
5
.
2
6
0
.
0
3
5
.
1
9
7
.
1
5
2
.
1
4
0
.
2
6
5
.
1
3
2
.
3
1
5
.
3
6
6
.
0
−
2
3
.
2
9
9
.
1
2
5
.
1
4
7
.
0
2
2
.
1
0
9
.
2
−
0
7
.
2
8
4
.
1
4
0
.
2
2
8
.
0
9
2
.
0
9
5
.
0
2
2
.
0
8
7
.
0
1
2
.
1
1
7
.
0
3
1
.
0
1
3
.
0
7
8
.
2
5
1
.
1
0
1
.
0
0
5
.
1
1
0
.
1
4
6
.
1
—
4
9
.
0
0
9
.
0
0
9
.
0
9
4
.
1
8
3
.
8
0
2
.
3
8
7
.
2
3
3
.
3
6
3
.
3
6
3
.
3
6
6
.
5
4
5
.
6
9
9
.
3
4
3
.
4
0
6
.
3
5
9
.
4
1
3
.
6
−
0
2
.
1
—
0
7
.
5
4
1
.
3
6
5
.
2
3
1
.
2
7
3
.
0
2
0
0
.
0
3
9
.
0
3
0
.
1
5
5
.
0
1
4
.
0
−
3
9
.
1
8
7
.
2
4
3
.
0
9
0
.
1
7
9
.
1
7
0
.
0
2
2
.
0
0
2
.
4
1
−
—
0
7
.
1
6
9
.
0
4
2
.
0
5
9
.
0
6
6
.
0
1
8
.
0
4
3
.
0
1
9
.
0
0
4
.
1
8
8
.
0
2
5
.
0
4
7
.
0
6
9
.
2
4
3
.
1
3
3
.
0
8
7
.
1
9
0
.
1
2
7
.
1
8
0
.
1
8
1
.
1
6
0
.
1
7
0
.
1
0
4
.
2
0
9
.
7
1
0
.
4
2
6
.
2
9
2
.
3
6
7
.
3
7
7
.
3
5
2
.
7
4
3
.
7
3
6
.
3
8
3
.
4
0
5
.
5
7
4
.
4
7
2
.
0
−
4
7
.
1
7
8
.
4
5
8
.
5
8
6
.
3
4
4
.
3
3
3
.
0
0
3
.
1
6
6
.
0
0
5
.
0
0
0
.
1
9
2
.
1
2
8
.
0
H
S
e
D
A
l
G
N
A
B
A
ich
S
A
H
T
u
Ö
S
N
A
T
u
H
B
A
ich
D
N
ICH
l
A
P
e
N
A
k
N
A
L
ich
R
S
N
A
T
S
ich
k
A
P
l
A
T
Ö
T
C
fi
ich
C
A
P
;
A
ich
S
A
T
S
A
e
H
T
u
Ö
S
D
N
A
T
S
A
E
2
7
.
2
6
9
.
2
6
8
.
0
0
4
.
1
8
9
.
1
2
6
.
0
2
1
.
0
5
3
.
0
0
9
.
2
−
9
1
.
2
5
1
.
1
4
8
.
0
A
ich
D
Ö
B
M
A
C
A
ich
S
e
N
Ö
D
N
ICH
R
D
P
Ö
A
L
A
ich
S
j
A
l
A
M
M
S
F
C
R
P
ich
J
ich
F
e
T
S
e
L
–
R
Ö
M
T
ich
S
e
N
ich
P
P
ich
l
ich
H
P
M
A
N
T
e
ich
V
l
A
T
Ö
T
A
ich
S
A
l
A
T
Ö
T
.
A
N
ich
H
C
F
Ö
C
ich
l
B
u
P
e
R
S
'
e
l
P
Ö
e
P
=
C
R
P
,
C
ich
l
B
u
P
e
R
C
ich
T
A
R
C
Ö
M
e
D
S
'
e
l
P
Ö
e
P
Ö
A
L
=
R
D
P
Ö
A
L
,
A
ich
S
e
N
Ö
R
C
ich
M
F
Ö
S
e
T
A
T
S
D
e
T
A
R
e
D
e
F
=
M
S
F
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
/
.
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
.
9
6
9
3
2
/
6
8
9
0
1
/
e
l
D
N
A
H
/
G
R
Ö
.
k
N
A
B
D
l
R
Ö
w
.
e
G
D
e
l
w
Ö
N
k
N
e
P
Ö
/
/
:
S
P
T
T
H
.
6
1
0
2
S
R
Ö
T
A
C
ich
D
N
ICH
T
N
e
M
P
Ö
l
e
v
e
D
D
l
R
Ö
W
.
6
1
0
2
.
k
N
A
B
D
l
R
Ö
W
N
Ö
D
e
S
A
B
S
N
Ö
ich
T
A
l
u
C
l
A
C
'
S
R
Ö
H
T
u
A
:
e
C
R
u
Ö
S
G
Ö
L
−
)
R
e
k
R
Ö
w
R
e
P
D
e
D
D
A
e
u
l
A
v
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
(
)
R
e
k
R
Ö
w
R
e
P
D
e
D
D
A
e
u
l
A
v
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
(
)
R
e
k
R
Ö
w
R
e
P
D
e
D
D
A
e
u
l
A
v
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
(
G
Ö
L
D
=
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
R
Ö
B
A
l
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
G
Ö
L
=
P
A
G
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
R
Ö
B
A
L
C
)
R
e
k
R
Ö
w
R
e
P
D
e
D
D
A
e
u
l
A
v
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
(
G
Ö
L
D
=
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
R
Ö
B
A
l
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
:
S
e
T
Ö
N
A
B
120 Asiatischer Entwicklungsbericht
Figur 1. The Gap between Nonagricultural Labor Productivity (nonagricultural value
added per worker) and Agricultural Labor Productivity (agricultural value added per worker)
in South Asia by Economy
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
/
.
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
logagrivapw = logarithm of agricultural value added per worker, lognoagrivapw = logarithm of nonagricultural value
added per worker.
Quelle: Authors’ calculations based on World Bank. 2016. World Development Indicators 2016. https://
openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/23969.
Figuren 1 Und 2 confirm these results graphically. Figur 1 plots labor
productivity in the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors in South Asian
economies over time. The productivity gap was initially small in many economies
(in the 1960s and 1970s), but it has expanded over the years. Figur 2 indicates that
the above results are broadly similar for East and Southeast Asian economies. If we
aggregate these data, the divergence of labor productivity between the agricultural
and nonagricultural sectors can be confirmed for all of Asia.
Nächste, we will examine whether agricultural
labor productivity (oder
nonagricultural labor productivity) has converged across different economies based
on the following simple static model (FE model) and dynamic panel model (System
generalized method of moments). The idea is similar to Ghosh (2006), WHO
examined the convergence of agricultural productivity among Indian states during
1960–2001. He found that there was significant divergence in labor productivity,
particularly after the early 1990s, while there was no significant convergence or
divergence in land productivity and per capita agricultural output. To take account
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 121
Figur 2. The Gap between Agricultural Labor and Nonagricultural Labor Productivity
in East and Southeast Asia, by Economy
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
/
.
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
FSM = Federated States of Micronesia, Lao PDR = Lao People’s Democratic Republic, logagrivapw = logarithm of
agricultural value added per worker, lognoagrivapw = logarithm of nonagricultural value added per worker, PRC =
Volksrepublik China.
Quelle: Authors’ calculations based on World Bank. 2016. World Development Indicators 2016. https://
openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/23969.
122 Asiatischer Entwicklungsbericht
of the business cycle, we have taken the 5-year averages and estimate the same
models as follows. We have redefined the time periods as t = 1 for 1960–1964,
t = 2 for 1965–1969, . . . , and t = 11 for 2010–2014. A selection of the
economies is guided by the availability of variables: 37 middle-income and low-
income economies have been chosen from Asia and the Pacific.
Erste, the static model (FE model) is specified as
d log AGLPit = β0 + β 1 log AGLPit−1 + β2T + Xit · β3 + β4d log NAGLPit−1
+ μi + εit
(5)
where d log AGLPit stands for the annual agricultural labor productivity growth at
time t for economy i. log AGLPit−1 is the level of agricultural productivity one period
earlier in order to capture the convergence effect following the empirical literature
to test the Solow growth model. Our main hypothesis for convergence is to test
whether β1 is negative.
T is the linear time trend. Xit
is a vector of control variables, wie zum Beispiel
the logarithm of schooling years, the logarithm of share of the mining sector in
BIP (in order to capture the economy’s resource dependency), and the lagged
level of inequality (based on the Gini coefficient). A selection of explanatory
variables draws upon the recent literature, which investigated the interactions
between agricultural growth and nonagricultural growth (Christiaensen, Demery,
and Kuhl 2011; Imai, Cheng, and Gaiha 2017). The average years of total schooling
is based on the Barro–Lee data, which has been commonly used in the empirical
macroeconomics literature as it is a broad measure of the human capital stock of
the economy.5 It is assumed that as the economy’s educational attainment improves,
agricultural or nonagricultural labor productivity improves. The GDP share of the
mining sector captures the extent to which the economy relies on natural resources,
which may undermine sectoral labor productivity. The degree of inequality in
various ways influences the sectoral labor productivity. Zum Beispiel, if there exists
a threshold (based on the nutritional requirement) below which workers cannot
work efficiently in the labor market, a high level of inequality may undermine
either agricultural or nonagricultural labor productivity. d log NAGLPit−1 is the
lagged annual nonagricultural productivity growth to capture the transmission
effect of labor productivity growth in the nonagricultural sector. This draws upon
Vollrath’s (2009) Modell, which showed that nonagricultural labor productivity
enhances agricultural labor productivity over time in a dual-economy setting.
μi is the economy’s unobservable fixed effect (z.B., cultural or institutional factors).
εit is an error term. We estimate this model with and without control variables, oder
5For more details, see Barro–Lee Educational Attainment Dataset. http://www.barrolee.com/.
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
.
/
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 123
the nonagricultural labor productivity growth term, while the results are robust to
inclusion (exclusion) of a few other explanatory variables.
As an extension, equation (1) has been estimated using the dynamic panel
Modell (system generalized method of moments) drawing upon the Blundell and
Bond (1998) robust estimator:
d log AGLPit = β0 + β1d log AGLPit−1 + β2 log AGLPit−1 + β3T
+ β4d log NAGLPit−1 + εit
(6)
Hier, d denotes the first difference. The lagged dependent variable captures the
persistent effect of agricultural labor productivity growth. Control variables have
been dropped as they are statistically insignificant.
Exactly the same models can be estimated for nonagricultural
Arbeit
productivity growth by static and dynamic panel models as in equations (7) Und
(8). The same models have been applied to subsamples for South Asia and for East
und Südostasien:
d log NAGLPit = β0 + β1 log NAGLPit−5 + β2T + Xit · β3 + β4d log AGLPit−1
+ μi + εit
d log NAGLPit = β0 + β1d log NAGLPit−1 + β2 log NAGLPit−5 + β3T
+ β4d log AGLPit−1 + μi + εit
(7)
(8)
In Table 2, the above models are estimated by using the 5-year average
Daten. Hier, the presence of convergence effect can be tested by checking whether
the lagged agricultural labor productivity (agricultural value added per worker
[t − 1]) is negative and statistically significant in Cases 1–4, and whether lagged
nonagricultural labor productivity (nonagricultural value added per worker [t − 1])
is negative and statistically significant in Cases 5–8. The result of a positive effect of
agricultural productivity on nonagricultural productivity (Cases 1–4) is important
as this is consistent with the prediction of Vollrath’s (2009) model that there is
diffusion from the agricultural sector. This is important in terms of the literature
on structural transformation in Asia (Reardon and Timmer 2014), which suggests
that the transformation of the agricultural sector (z.B., commercialization and
product diversification) is becoming closely linked to changes in dietary patterns;
supply chain and retail revolution; and integrated labor, Land, and credit markets.
Hier, the whole process of structural transformation implies a positive diffusion
effect of agricultural labor productivity on nonagricultural labor productivity.
Jedoch, contrary to Vollrath’s prediction, a positive effect of nonagricultural labor
productivity on agricultural labor productivity was not observed as many Asian
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
.
/
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
124 Asiatischer Entwicklungsbericht
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
R
Ö
B
A
L
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
R
Ö
B
A
L
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
:
e
l
B
A
ich
R
A
V
T
N
e
D
N
e
P
e
D
:
e
l
B
A
ich
R
A
V
T
N
e
D
N
e
P
e
D
)
e
G
A
R
e
v
A
R
A
e
j
–
5
,
A
ich
S
A
(
S
R
Ö
T
C
e
S
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
D
N
A
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
e
H
T
N
ich
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
R
Ö
B
A
L
F
Ö
e
C
N
e
G
R
e
v
N
Ö
C
.
2
e
l
B
A
T
M
M
G
S
8
e
S
A
C
*
*
0
4
3
0
.
6
3
1
0
0
.
)
5
4
1
0
(
.
)
6
5
7
0
0
(
.
D
e
X
ich
F
S
T
C
e
F
F
E
7
e
S
A
C
*
1
8
2
0
.
)
0
6
1
0
(
.
D
e
X
ich
F
S
T
C
e
F
F
E
6
e
S
A
C
D
e
X
ich
F
S
T
C
e
F
F
E
5
e
S
A
C
*
*
*
8
1
3
.
0
)
7
1
1
.
0
(
*
*
*
5
0
–
e
3
7
2
−
.
*
*
*
4
2
1
0
0
0
0
−
.
*
*
*
5
0
–
e
6
5
.
9
−
*
*
*
1
1
1
0
0
0
.
0
−
)
6
0
–
e
5
7
7
(
.
)
5
0
–
e
9
1
3
(
.
)
5
0
–
e
7
7
.
1
(
)
5
0
–
e
8
2
.
2
(
M
M
G
S
4
e
S
A
C
*
*
1
3
3
.
0
)
1
4
1
.
0
(
*
*
4
5
1
.
0
−
*
*
6
0
–
e
1
6
.
2
−
)
9
7
7
0
.
0
(
)
6
0
–
e
2
2
.
1
(
D
e
X
ich
F
S
T
C
e
F
F
E
3
e
S
A
C
D
e
X
ich
F
S
T
C
e
F
F
E
2
e
S
A
C
D
e
X
ich
F
S
T
C
e
F
F
E
1
e
S
A
C
)
8
1
4
0
.
0
(
*
5
0
–
e
1
9
.
2
−
)
5
0
–
e
5
4
.
1
(
*
*
0
0
1
.
0
−
)
5
5
5
0
.
0
(
6
0
–
e
6
5
.
3
−
1
0
4
0
.
0
−
)
6
0
–
e
9
1
.
2
(
*
*
6
0
–
e
7
2
.
4
–
)
6
0
–
e
1
9
.
1
(
6
4
4
0
0
0
.
)
3
7
4
0
0
0
(
.
)
5
4
5
0
0
(
.
1
7
1
0
.
4
8
1
7
3
9
1
1
0
0
.
3
8
8
0
0
0
.
)
2
0
2
0
0
(
.
)
4
4
1
0
(
.
*
0
5
8
0
0
0
.
)
0
3
4
0
0
0
(
.
8
8
1
0
0
.
)
6
9
1
0
0
(
.
7
4
1
0
−
.
)
0
0
2
0
(
.
3
2
1
7
5
2
0
.
3
2
*
*
*
8
6
2
0
.
0
)
0
5
7
0
0
.
0
(
)
0
5
4
0
.
0
(
3
2
1
.
0
2
2
2
8
3
0
6
1
.
0
*
*
*
0
0
2
0
.
0
)
5
5
6
0
0
.
0
(
)
5
8
4
0
.
0
(
8
0
2
.
0
5
8
1
7
3
3
5
2
.
0
*
*
6
5
9
0
0
.
0
)
6
8
3
0
0
.
0
(
2
5
6
0
0
.
0
−
)
7
7
3
0
.
0
(
5
5
1
7
3
7
7
3
0
0
.
0
)
1
0
1
0
.
0
(
6
6
3
0
.
0
−
)
3
0
1
.
0
(
4
2
4
0
0
.
0
)
9
5
2
0
0
.
0
(
3
0
2
0
.
0
)
8
1
1
0
.
0
(
8
3
1
.
0
−
)
1
1
2
.
0
(
2
0
1
7
9
1
.
0
3
2
*
*
2
0
1
0
.
0
)
4
8
4
0
0
.
0
(
4
4
1
0
.
0
−
)
2
6
4
0
.
0
(
*
*
7
9
1
0
.
0
)
2
3
7
0
0
.
0
(
8
1
1
.
0
−
)
5
2
6
0
.
0
(
7
3
5
5
1
3
3
0
.
0
7
7
1
4
5
0
.
0
7
3
)
1
−
)
1
−
T
(
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
T
(
H
T
w
Ö
R
G
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
R
Ö
B
A
l
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
R
Ö
B
A
l
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
S
e
l
B
A
ich
R
A
V
l
e
D
Ö
M
R
Ö
B
A
l
)
1
−
T
(
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
N
Ö
N
e
H
T
F
Ö
e
R
A
H
S
G
Ö
L
P
D
G
N
ich
R
Ö
T
C
e
S
G
N
ich
N
ich
M
S
R
A
e
j
G
N
ich
l
Ö
Ö
H
C
S
G
Ö
L
)
1
−
T
(
X
e
D
N
ich
j
T
ich
l
A
u
Q
e
N
ICH
D
N
e
R
T
e
M
ich
T
R
A
e
N
ich
L
S
e
ich
M
Ö
N
Ö
C
e
F
Ö
R
e
B
M
u
N
S
N
Ö
ich
T
A
v
R
e
S
B
Ö
D
e
R
A
u
Q
S
–
R
T
N
A
T
S
N
Ö
C
)
1
−
T
(
j
T
ich
v
ich
T
C
u
D
Ö
R
P
R
Ö
B
A
l
l
A
R
u
T
l
u
C
ich
R
G
A
l
D
Ö
w
N
Ö
A
D
e
D
F
R
Ö
M
H
T
T
P
:
/
/
D
ich
R
e
C
T
.
M
ich
T
.
/
e
D
u
A
D
e
v
/
A
R
T
ich
C
e
–
P
D
l
F
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
A
D
e
v
_
A
_
0
0
1
2
5
P
D
.
/
F
B
j
G
u
e
S
T
T
Ö
N
0
8
S
e
P
e
M
B
e
R
2
0
2
3
.
9
6
9
3
2
/
6
8
9
0
1
/
e
l
D
N
A
H
/
G
R
Ö
.
k
N
A
B
D
l
R
Ö
w
.
e
G
D
e
l
w
Ö
N
k
N
e
P
Ö
/
/
:
S
P
T
T
H
.
6
1
0
2
S
R
Ö
T
A
C
ich
D
N
ICH
T
N
e
M
P
Ö
l
e
v
e
D
D
l
R
Ö
W
.
6
1
0
2
.
k
N
A
B
D
l
R
Ö
W
N
Ö
D
e
S
A
B
S
N
Ö
ich
T
A
l
u
C
l
A
C
'
S
R
Ö
H
T
u
A
:
e
C
R
u
Ö
S
.
S
T
N
e
M
Ö
M
F
Ö
D
Ö
H
T
e
M
D
e
z
ich
l
A
R
e
N
e
G
M
e
T
S
j
S
.
1
.
0
<
p
*
,
5
0
.
0
<
p
*
*
,
1
0
.
0
<
p
*
*
*
.
s
e
s
e
h
t
n
e
r
a
p
n
i
s
r
o
r
r
e
d
r
a
d
n
a
t
s
t
s
u
b
o
R
:
s
e
t
o
N
=
M
M
G
S
,
t
c
u
d
o
r
p
c
i
t
s
e
m
o
d
s
s
o
r
g
=
P
D
G
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 125
economies were primarily dependent on the agricultural sector during our data
period.
In Table 2, we confirm that
labor productivity converges in both the
agricultural and nonagricultural sectors, and the convergence effect is significant
in all the cases except Case 2. This implies “a catching-up effect” in which the
economies with relatively low agricultural labor productivity tend to catch up with
those having relatively high agricultural labor productivity. The catching up effect
is also found for nonagricultural labor productivity.
We have also found that lagged nonagricultural labor productivity growth
deters agricultural labor productivity growth (Cases 3 and 4). This is consistent with
the theoretical model of Vollrath (2009) that an improvement of nonagricultural
productivity induces agricultural workers to work more efficiently. However, the
result is reversed when we use the annual panel data in which nonagricultural labor
productivity is lagged by 5 years. Here, lagged nonagricultural labor productivity
growth is found to promote agricultural labor productivity growth as predicted by
the theoretical model.6
On the other hand, we have found, based on the 5-year average panel,
that lagged agricultural labor productivity growth promotes nonagricultural labor
productivity growth (Cases 5, 7, and 8). In Case 8,
the lagged agricultural
productivity growth is treated as an endogenous variable. Other covariates
are mostly statistically insignificant, but a large lagged inequality increases
nonagricultural labor productivity growth in Case 7.
We have estimated the same models using the 5-year average data only
for South Asia. A statistically significant convergence effect is found in the case
of agricultural labor productivity growth. For the cross-sectoral effects, lagged
agricultural labor productivity growth is found to promote nonagricultural labor
productivity growth. For South Asia, a higher level of inequality tends to reduce
overall agricultural labor productivity growth with some lag. Given that inequality
can dampen the productivity of the disadvantaged group of agricultural workers
or poor smallholders, this is a plausible result.7 When we replicate the same
regressions for East and Southeast Asia, we find that convergence effects are
generally found to be significant. For the cross-sectoral effect, lagged agricultural
labor productivity growth positively affects nonagricultural labor productivity
growth.8
6The results based on the annual panel will be provided on request.
7For South Asian economies,
the Gini coefficient
is positively correlated with the agricultural
commercialization index based on the extent to which an agricultural product is processed (Imai, Gaiha, and Bresciani
2016); the coefficient of correlation is 0.067. For East and Southeast Asian economies, the correlation is negative
with a coefficient of –0.4. This could explain the negative correlation between inequality and agricultural labor
productivity for South Asia, though the causality will have to be examined carefully in future studies.
8The disaggregated results will be provided on request.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
126 Asian Development Review
IV. Effects of the Labor Productivity Gap between the Agricultural and
Nonagricultural Sectors on Poverty, Inequality, and the Sectoral
Population Share
We have so far examined the pattern of (i) the convergence of labor
productivity between the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors, and (ii) the
convergence of agricultural or nonagricultural productivity across different
economies. Overall, agricultural
labor productivity growth has promoted
nonagricultural productivity growth and the sectoral gap has widened, while the
between-economy disparity of the sectoral labor productivity has narrowed. These
findings are broadly consistent with the theoretical model of Vollrath (2009).
is, a change toward higher nonagricultural
An interesting empirical question is how this process will dynamically affect
poverty and inequality as well as labor allocation across different sectors over time.
As we discussed in section II, the theoretical model implies that an increase of
the sectoral gap tends to be generally less egalitarian, or that there is an increase
in inequality when both sectors grow (Bourguignon 1990). However, it is not
straightforward to answer the question because of the difficulty in disentangling the
complex causal links from the labor productivity gap between the agricultural and
nonagricultural sectors to poverty (or inequality or the sectoral population share).
For instance, an increase in the labor productivity gap may imply a divergence:
labor productivity (reflecting
that
technological development) and/or lower or more stagnant agricultural productivity.
On the other hand, a reduction in the gap may imply a change toward convergence
due to stagnant nonagricultural labor productivity and/or an increase in agricultural
labor productivity. However, while the larger gap affects poverty or inequality,
the higher poverty rates or inequality might also influence the gap. For instance,
poor people in rural areas cannot invest in a profitable investment in agriculture
that would require a certain amount of investment in physical and human capital
(e.g., machinery or high-yielding crops), which hinders the growth of labor
productivity in agricultural areas. Thus, there is a need for instrumenting the labor
productivity gap because it may be endogenous.
We have tackled the endogeneity by instrumenting the labor productivity gap
by (i) the lagged agricultural product diversity index (Imai, Gaiha, and Bresciani
2016) and (ii) the lagged logarithm of the production share of the mining sector
in GDP.9 The first instrument is used as a proxy for agricultural transformation by
9This draws upon Remans et al. (2014), who use an index called the Shannon Entropy Diversity Metric to
(cid:4)
capture production diversity at the country level using FAOSTAT. It is defined as H (cid:4) = −
R
i=1 pi ln pi where R is
the number of agricultural products and pi is the share of production for the item, i, available from FAOSTAT. The
production share, pi, is defined in terms of the monetary value at a local price for each product, i. If the country
produces more agricultural products, including processed and unprocessed crops, and the monetary value of all
products is more evenly divided among different items, the diversity index, H (cid:4), takes a larger value. On the contrary,
if the country produces a smaller number of agricultural products and the monetary value of one or two specific
products is large, H (cid:4) is smaller.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 127
Imai, Gaiha, and Bresciani (2016), and is supposed to affect the labor productivity
gap, mainly by influencing agricultural labor productivity. However, the change
of the production pattern itself cannot directly influence poverty or inequality.
We cannot deny the possibility that the process of specialization could increase
poverty, for instance, as there may be less demand for manual labor; but we
can reasonably assume that poverty can change through adjustments in farm
production or income (per worker). The second instrument could also reduce the
labor productivity gap because dependence on the mining sector could deter the
overall effort for technological progress in the industrial sector, without directly
affecting poverty. The reliance on the mining sector could affect poverty directly
(e.g., the impoverishment of manual workers in the mining sector), but we assume
that this does not have a direct impact on poverty, particularly in rural areas. We
assume that the productivity or income effect is larger than the direct effect on
poverty, while we admit limitations in using the second instrument.10 We have
applied the IV model in the panel framework using the FE-IV model, whereby
the unobservable country effect is taken into account. Because we focus on the
relatively longer-term effect, we use only the 5-year average data.
In the first stage, we will estimate the determinants of the labor productivity
gap between the two sectors:
Gapit−1 = β0 + β1d log AGLPit−1 + β2d log NAGLPit−1 + β3Sit−1 + β4Miningit−2
+ μi + εit
(9)
+ β5Product Diversityit−2
Here, t stands for each 5-year period: t = 1 for 1960–1964, t = 2 for 1965–1969,
. . . , t = 11 for 2010–2014. Gapit−1 is the first lag of normalized difference between
nonagricultural value added per worker and agricultural value added per worker
(at purchasing power parity [PPP] in US dollars divided by 1,000). d log AGLPit−1
is the lag of the first difference in log of agricultural value added per worker:
that is, the agricultural labor productivity growth during the preceding period.
Likewise, d log NAGLPit−1 is the nonagricultural labor productivity growth during
the preceding period. Sit−1 is the lag of schooling years. μi is the unobservable
country fixed effect and εit is an error term (independent and identically distributed).
Instruments for the labor productivity gap between the agricultural and
nonagricultural sectors are the second lag of the production share of the mining
sector (Miningit−2) and the second lag of the agricultural product diversity
index. These instruments, despite the limitations, are justified on the following
grounds. Since the mining sector share is a variable closely associated with the
(broadly predetermined) factor endowment of the economy, it will have a direct
effect on the economy’s labor allocations across different sectors, including the
10These sets of instruments are the best candidates given the data availability.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
128 Asian Development Review
rural agricultural sector, rural nonagricultural sector (nonmining or mining), and
urban nonagricultural sector (nonmining or mining). Depending on the degree
of dependence on mining resources, the allocation of labor across sectors and
worker efforts in each sector are influenced directly. It is surmised here that
the effect of the mining sector share first influences sectoral labor productivity,
rather than poverty. While the mining sector share may influence poverty directly
(e.g., through the impoverishment of mining workers), we assume that it mainly
influences the relative sectoral productivity. The second instrument, the product
diversity index, affects agricultural labor productivity directly as more diversified
production implies the economy’s adoption of profitable and marketable agricultural
products (e.g., vegetables, fruits, meat). The index also influences nonagricultural
labor productivity as the introduction of these products influences the productivity
of the food processing sector. However, it is unlikely that the product diversity index
directly affects poverty or inequality. These instruments, despite the limitations,
have been validated by specification tests.
In the second stage, poverty is estimated by the (instrumented) labor
productivity gap as well as other determinants:
(cid:5)Gapit−1
= γ0 + γ1
Povertyit
+ γ2d log AGLPit−1 + γ3d log NAGLPit−1 + γ4Sit−1
+ θi + eit
(10)
Equations (9) and (10) are estimated using the FE-IV model. Poverty is defined in
various ways, including (i) the national poverty headcount, or poverty gap, based on
the international poverty line of $1.9 (extreme poverty) or $3.1 (moderate poverty)
per day at PPP in 2011 (World Bank 2016); (ii) the rural poverty headcount, poverty
gap, or poverty gap squared, based on $1.25 (extreme poverty) or $2 (moderate
poverty) at PPP in 2005; and (iii) the same urban poverty indexes in (ii), based on
household data in rural areas.11 In one case, we have replaced poverty by the Gini
coefficient evaluated at the national or subnational level (for rural and urban areas
separately). Finally, given the data limitations, we have derived the population share
of the rural sector, nonagricultural sector, and urban sector, and used each share
as a dependent variable in the second-stage regression (Imai, Gaiha, and Garbero
2017). This aims to examine how the labor productivity gap will influence the
labor allocation in the middle to long run. In all cases, the endogeneity of the labor
productivity gap is instrumented.
First, we have estimated national poverty in the second stage (the upper left
panel of Table 3).12 In the first stage, one of the instruments, the agricultural product
11The difference in the definitions of rural, urban, and national poverty reflects the data availability. Poverty
estimates for (ii) and (iii) have been provided by the Strategy and Knowledge Department of the International Fund
for Agricultural Development.
12A full set of the regression results will be provided upon request. We provide only the second-stage results
in Table 3.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 129
y
t
i
l
a
u
q
e
n
I
d
n
a
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
n
o
s
r
o
t
c
e
S
l
a
r
u
t
l
u
c
i
r
g
a
n
o
N
d
n
a
l
a
r
u
t
l
u
c
i
r
g
A
e
h
t
n
e
e
w
t
e
b
p
a
G
y
t
i
v
i
t
c
u
d
o
r
P
r
o
b
a
L
e
h
t
f
o
s
t
c
e
f
f
E
.
3
e
l
b
a
T
)
l
e
d
o
m
V
I
-
E
F
e
h
t
f
o
e
g
a
t
s
d
n
o
c
e
s
(
l
a
r
u
R
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
p
a
G
d
e
r
a
u
q
S
)
2
$ ( l a r u R y t r e v o P p a G ) 2 $
(
l
a
r
u
R
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
t
n
u
o
c
d
a
e
H
)
2
$ ( l a r u R y t r e v o P p a G d e r a u q S ) 5 2 . 1 $
(
l
a
r
u
R
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
p
a
G
)
5
2
.
1
$ ( * * 5 6 4 1 − . * * 7 5 3 1 − . * * 7 1 1 . 1 − 1 9 2 . 1 − * * 3 3 6 . 1 − ) 2 6 6 0 ( . 2 5 1 1 − . ) 3 9 5 0 ( . 8 0 0 1 − . ) 4 0 5 0 ( . 4 0 9 . 0 − ) 0 6 6 1 ( . ) 2 2 4 1 ( . ) 9 0 1 . 1 ( 4 1 2 0 . ) 0 4 0 1 ( . ) 9 9 7 0 ( . 2 3 9 0 − . 4 2 5 0 . 5 4 2 1 . d e u n i t n o C 2 7 1 0 . ) 6 8 8 0 ( . ) 4 0 7 0 ( . 4 8 5 0 − . 6 0 5 0 . 5 4 2 1 0 9 1 . 0 ) 9 7 6 . 0 ( ) 2 9 5 . 0 ( 4 7 1 . 0 − 5 5 4 . 0 5 4 2 1 ) 4 6 6 . 2 ( 1 6 9 . 2 ) 1 4 8 . 2 ( ) 7 9 7 . 0 ( 7 3 5 . 1 − ) 6 8 0 . 2 ( ) 2 7 1 . 1 ( 2 3 1 . 1 − 0 6 3 . 0 ) 3 1 3 . 1 ( * * 3 7 5 . 8 − ) 9 1 1 . 4 ( ) 1 3 9 . 0 ( 8 6 3 . 1 − 5 4 1 6 5 . 0 2 1 7 5 5 . 0 5 4 2 1 l a r u R y t r e v o P t n u o c d a e H ) 5 2 . 1 $
(
*
*
0
2
6
.
1
−
)
4
3
7
.
0
(
6
7
1
.
1
−
)
6
3
7
.
1
(
9
5
1
.
0
)
3
7
0
.
1
(
)
8
8
8
.
0
(
6
7
7
.
0
−
9
7
4
.
0
5
4
2
1
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
p
a
G
)
1
.
3
$ ( 4 9 3 . 0 − ) 9 5 4 . 0 ( 3 6 0 . 3 − ) 2 4 9 . 2 ( 3 7 3 . 0 ) 8 5 3 . 2 ( ) 6 5 0 . 1 ( 0 7 4 . 1 − 3 7 2 . 0 7 7 1 1 t n u o c d a e H ) 1 . 3 $
(
4
7
0
.
0
−
)
1
0
6
.
0
(
3
9
7
.
2
−
)
7
0
2
.
3
(
4
5
1
.
0
)
5
1
6
.
2
(
)
4
2
2
.
1
(
6
4
7
.
1
−
0
7
1
.
0
7
7
1
1
1
8
0
.
0
)
4
6
4
.
0
(
4
9
8
.
3
−
)
7
5
8
.
2
(
5
9
3
.
0
)
9
0
3
.
2
(
)
3
2
0
.
1
(
3
1
6
.
1
−
0
9
1
.
0
7
7
1
1
4
2
2
.
0
−
)
1
8
4
.
0
(
5
4
4
.
3
−
)
0
4
9
.
2
(
3
5
5
.
0
)
6
6
3
.
2
(
)
5
8
0
.
1
(
0
6
6
.
1
−
1
5
2
.
0
7
7
1
1
p
a
G
)
9
.
1
$ ( t n u o c d a e H ) 9 . 1 $
(
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
)
1
−
t
(
p
a
G
s
e
l
b
a
i
r
a
V
l
a
r
u
t
l
u
c
i
r
g
A
)
1
−
t
(
h
t
w
o
r
g
y
t
i
v
i
t
c
u
d
o
r
p
)
1
−
t
(
h
t
w
o
r
g
y
t
i
v
i
t
c
u
d
o
r
p
l
a
r
u
t
l
u
c
i
r
g
a
n
o
N
)
1
−
t
(
s
r
a
e
y
g
n
i
l
o
o
h
c
s
g
o
L
s
n
o
i
t
a
v
r
e
s
b
O
d
e
r
a
u
q
s
-
R
f
o
r
e
b
m
u
N
s
e
i
m
o
n
o
c
e
130 Asian Development Review
*
2
3
0
5
.
n
a
b
r
U
e
r
a
h
S
)
5
3
5
2
(
.
7
9
0
5
−
.
l
a
r
u
R
.
i
r
g
a
–
n
o
N
e
r
a
h
S
*
*
*
1
8
0
3
.
)
1
8
2
8
(
.
0
4
9
5
.
)
1
9
4
7
(
.
)
0
5
6
7
1
(
.
)
0
0
9
1
2
(
.
)
2
4
1
.
0
(
)
3
8
1
.
0
(
.
*
*
6
4
4
2
−
)
4
9
2
8
(
.
.
2
4
2
1
−
5
1
1
0
.
0
−
)
1
7
9
0
.
0
(
8
9
1
.
0
−
6
3
1
.
0
)
7
4
1
.
0
(
1
8
2
.
0
−
*
*
*
6
3
6
.
4
−
4
5
8
.
6
−
*
*
*
8
5
0
.
2
−
*
*
*
4
6
8
.
1
−
)
4
7
1
.
1
(
6
1
3
.
6
)
5
2
9
.
3
(
*
9
0
9
.
8
)
7
6
9
.
4
(
)
4
8
0
.
5
(
)
6
1
7
.
0
(
0
5
2
0
.
0
−
)
7
8
2
.
1
(
)
8
8
4
.
0
(
8
8
1
.
0
−
)
2
5
0
.
1
(
)
1
9
8
.
1
(
4
7
0
.
2
−
6
1
3
.
0
)
1
1
7
.
1
(
l
a
r
u
R
e
r
a
h
S
n
a
b
r
U
i
n
i
G
l
a
r
u
R
i
n
i
G
l
a
n
o
i
t
a
N
d
e
r
a
u
q
S
i
n
i
G
)
2
$ ( n a b r U y t r e v o P p a G n a b r U y t r e v o P p a G ) 2 $
(
n
a
b
r
U
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
n
a
b
r
U
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
p
a
G
t
n
u
o
c
d
a
e
H
d
e
r
a
u
q
S
)
2
$ ( ) 5 2 . 1 $
(
.
d
e
u
n
i
t
n
o
C
.
3
e
l
b
a
T
n
a
b
r
U
y
t
r
e
v
o
P
p
a
G
)
5
2
.
1
$ ( * * 7 1 3 . 3 − ) 3 8 5 . 1 ( 5 2 5 . 0 − ) 2 0 7 . 1 ( n a b r U y t r e v o P t n u o c d a e H ) 5 2 . 1 $
(
0
0
4
.
9
1
−
)
0
4
7
.
2
1
(
*
0
1
2
.
6
2
)
8
1
.
4
1
(
*
6
8
5
8
.
)
8
4
0
5
(
.
3
5
9
9
−
.
)
3
4
9
1
(
.
7
4
5
5
.
)
0
9
9
4
1
(
.
0
5
7
0
0
.
0
)
6
8
0
.
0
(
1
6
2
0
.
0
)
6
0
1
.
0
(
*
*
3
4
1
.
6
−
*
*
8
2
5
.
5
−
)
6
6
7
.
2
(
)
0
7
0
.
2
(
)
9
6
7
.
0
(
0
5
4
.
0
−
)
8
5
6
.
0
(
4
7
1
.
0
−
)
4
1
1
.
1
(
9
4
7
.
0
−
)
4
6
0
.
1
(
4
6
5
.
0
−
)
9
5
8
.
5
(
*
*
8
6
.
5
1
−
)
5
0
4
7
(
.
)
5
7
8
8
(
.
6
5
6
8
−
.
*
*
*
7
3
9
3
−
.
*
*
*
4
3
6
4
.
)
9
7
6
8
(
.
8
6
4
3
0
0
.
0
1
9
2
6
0
.
4
2
6
6
8
6
0
.
4
2
6
*
4
3
2
.
0
)
7
3
1
.
0
(
3
4
6
5
3
.
0
2
1
9
9
2
0
.
0
−
)
7
7
1
.
0
(
5
4
3
0
0
.
0
−
2
1
*
*
*
3
7
6
.
8
)
1
5
8
.
2
(
)
9
4
2
.
7
(
5
6
2
.
5
−
)
3
1
1
.
1
(
7
3
7
.
0
−
)
8
1
6
.
0
(
5
3
1
.
0
−
)
0
9
0
.
2
(
2
0
7
.
0
−
7
7
3
6
0
.
0
2
1
2
4
6
5
2
.
0
2
1
2
4
9
8
6
.
0
2
1
9
8
6
.
0
3
4
2
1
8
2
4
.
0
9
3
1
1
1
6
2
.
0
)
1
3
6
.
1
(
2
4
5
.
0
2
4
2
1
1
7
2
.
0
4
4
2
1
)
7
9
.
3
1
(
5
6
.
1
1
−
)
1
−
t
(
p
a
G
s
e
l
b
a
i
r
a
V
l
a
r
u
t
l
u
c
i
r
g
A
)
1
−
t
(
h
t
w
o
r
g
y
t
i
v
i
t
c
u
d
o
r
p
)
1
−
t
(
h
t
w
o
r
g
y
t
i
v
i
t
c
u
d
o
r
p
l
a
r
u
t
l
u
c
i
r
g
a
n
o
N
)
1
−
t
(
s
r
a
e
y
g
n
i
l
o
o
h
c
s
g
o
L
s
n
o
i
t
a
v
r
e
s
b
O
d
e
r
a
u
q
s
-
R
f
o
r
e
b
m
u
N
s
e
i
m
o
n
o
c
e
y
t
r
e
v
o
p
e
h
t
e
r
a
s
g
n
i
d
a
e
h
n
m
u
l
o
c
e
h
t
w
o
l
e
b
s
e
s
e
h
t
n
e
r
a
p
e
h
t
e
d
i
s
n
i
s
e
u
l
a
V
.
1
.
0
<
p
*
,
5
0
.
0
<
p
*
*
,
1
0
.
0
<
p
*
*
*
d
e
t
i
n
U
n
i
y
t
i
r
a
p
r
e
w
o
p
g
n
i
s
a
h
c
r
u
p
t
a
(
r
e
k
r
o
w
r
e
p
d
e
d
d
a
e
u
l
a
v
l
a
r
u
t
l
u
c
i
r
g
a
d
n
a
r
e
k
r
o
w
r
e
p
d
e
d
d
a
e
u
l
a
v
l
a
r
u
t
l
u
c
i
r
g
a
n
o
n
.
s
e
s
e
h
t
n
e
r
a
p
n
i
s
r
o
r
r
e
d
r
a
d
n
a
t
s
t
s
u
b
o
R
.
)
0
0
0
,
1
y
b
d
e
d
i
v
i
d
s
r
a
l
l
o
d
s
e
t
a
t
S
.
s
e
n
i
l
n
e
e
w
t
e
b
e
c
n
e
r
e
f
f
i
d
d
e
z
i
l
a
m
r
o
n
e
h
t
o
t
s
r
e
f
e
r
”
p
a
G
“
:
s
e
t
o
N
.
e
l
b
a
i
r
a
v
l
a
t
n
e
m
u
r
t
s
n
i
s
t
c
e
f
f
e
d
e
x
fi
=
V
I
-
E
F
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
.
9
6
9
3
2
/
6
8
9
0
1
/
e
l
d
n
a
h
/
g
r
o
.
k
n
a
b
d
l
r
o
w
.
e
g
d
e
l
w
o
n
k
n
e
p
o
/
/
:
s
p
t
t
h
.
6
1
0
2
s
r
o
t
a
c
i
d
n
I
t
n
e
m
p
o
l
e
v
e
D
d
l
r
o
W
.
6
1
0
2
.
k
n
a
B
d
l
r
o
W
n
o
d
e
s
a
b
s
n
o
i
t
a
l
u
c
l
a
c
’
s
r
o
h
t
u
A
:
e
c
r
u
o
S
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 131
diversity in the preceding period, will reduce the labor productivity gap. That
is, if the structural transformation in the rural sector progresses and agricultural
production is more diversified, then the gap will be reduced, presumably because
agricultural sector productivity will catch up with nonagricultural productivity.
However, the first lagged agricultural productivity growth increases the gap. This
is counterintuitive, but if agricultural productivity growth promotes nonagricultural
growth without a lag, the period with faster agricultural productivity growth may
even match the period with faster nonagricultural growth. The coefficient estimate
labor productivity growth is negative, but not statistically
of nonagricultural
significant.13 Education tends to increase the gap.
The question arising from the analysis in the last section is why the labor
productivity gap has grown in some economies and not in other economies. It is
not easy to provide a definite answer, but our results imply that the agricultural
transformation reduces the gap and that improved human capital widens the gap.
In the second stage, we do not find any evidence that the gap influences
poverty at the national level with the coefficient estimate being negative (except
the second column) and statistically insignificant (the upper left panel of Table 3).14
We find that the number of schooling years is negative and statistically significant.
The F-statistic of excluded instruments is 16.34, which is above the threshold of 10,
and the Sargan overidentification test of all instruments is not significant (p-value
of 0.331), validating the IV estimation.
Next, we examine whether the labor productivity gap has affected poverty.
Because the sample is reduced, the results from the first stage have changed
slightly. For instance, nonagricultural productivity growth is now negative and
significant, while one of the instruments, the productivity–diversity index, is now
positive and significant. So, with a smaller sample, the progress of the agricultural
transformation tends to increase the labor productivity gap. The reason is not
clear, but in this case the agricultural transformation may have an instant impact
on improving both agricultural and nonagricultural labor productivity, with the
magnitude of the latter being comparatively larger.
In the second stage, the increase of the labor productivity gap tends to reduce
poverty in the rural regions regardless of the choice of poverty thresholds and
for all different measures of poverty (e.g., headcount, poverty gap, and poverty
gap squared except the third column for extreme poverty gap squared as shown
13The correlation between the labor productivity gap and nonagricultural labor productivity growth is positive
with a correlation coefficient of 0.034. The correlation coefficient between the gap and agricultural labor productivity
growth is 0.036. Not surprisingly, the correlation coefficient between the agricultural and nonagricultural sector
growth terms is high at 0.614. The highest variance inflation factor of the first-stage regression is 2.44, which is
below the threshold of 10 and which would justify the inclusion of labor productivity growth in both sectors at the
same time.
14We have also estimated the second-stage regressions by using the FE model without using IV. In this case,
the sample size is larger, but we have found that the lagged labor productivity gap reduces significantly both extreme
and moderate poverty, for both the headcount ratio and poverty gap.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
.
/
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
132 Asian Development Review
in the upper right panel of Table 3). That is, as nonagricultural labor productivity
grows faster than agricultural labor productivity, rural poverty significantly declines
in every dimension, including the share of the poor, the depth of rural poverty,
and inequality among the rural poor. This result may not be consistent with the
theoretical prediction by Bourguignon (1990) as the model suggests that the gap
between the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors tends to increase inequality
given elastic capital–labor substitution assumed in the modern sector. However,
Vollrath’s (2009) model implies that as nonagricultural labor productivity increases,
the efficiency of workers in the agricultural sector improves. If this helps the rural
poor escape from poverty, we expect that nonagricultural labor productivity growth
has the effect of reducing rural poverty. Here, the test of excluded instruments
(F-statistic) is 9.55, which is below the threshold of 10, partly because of the small
sample size, and so the results need to be interpreted with caution. The Sargan
statistic is not significant, justifying the use of IV.15
We have also estimated urban poverty in the second stage of the FE-IV
model. The results are shown in the lower left panel of Table 3. We have found
that the size of the poverty-reducing effect is much larger for urban poverty than
rural poverty. That is, as the gap between nonagricultural and agricultural labor
productivity expands, both urban poverty and rural poverty decrease, but urban
poverty tends to decline at a much faster rate. However, the results will have to
be interpreted with caution, particularly in cases where the F-statistic for excluded
instruments in the first stage is low (columns 2 and 3).
Finally, we have estimated the effect of the lagged labor productivity gap
on the Gini coefficient at the national, rural, and urban levels. As the sample sizes
differ, the result in the first column cannot be compared with the results in the
second and third columns. However, after controlling for the endogeneity of the
labor productivity gap, we have found evidence that the gap significantly reduces
the national Gini coefficient (the lower right panel of Table 3). In this case, the
first-stage F-statistic is larger than 10. The result is robust if we do not instrument
the labor productivity gap or if we use the smaller sample for which disaggregated
inequality data are available.
Using the disaggregated data, we have also estimated the effects of the
lagged labor productivity gap on the sectoral population share, drawing upon Imai,
Gaiha, and Garbero (2017). The results will have to be interpreted with caution,
specifically in the first and the second columns (due to the small sample size)
where the specification tests for IV do not validate the specifications. However,
we have found some evidence that the labor productivity gap reduces the rural
population share and increases the share of the rural nonagricultural sector. When
we use a larger sample size, we have found that the lagged productivity gap
15The lagged labor productivity gap is no longer statistically significant in explaining rural poverty for the
larger sample in the FE model without IV.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 133
increases the population share of the urban sector significantly. These results are
broadly consistent with the theoretical model of Vollrath (2009) where increases
in nonagricultural productivity will help industrialize the economy and induce
agricultural laborers to work more efficiently, while the share of the agricultural
sector declines over time. If this process benefits much of the population in rural
and urban areas, inequality is likely to decline over time. However, our result is not
consistent with Bourguignon’s (1990) model, which implies that the gap between
the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors tends to increase inequality.
In sum, we have found that the increase in the lagged labor productivity gap,
which is treated as endogenous, will reduce both urban and rural poverty as well as
national-level inequality. In particular, there is robust evidence confirming that the
labor productivity gap reduces urban poverty evaluated at the poverty threshold of
$2 per day.
IV. Conclusions
First, we have examined whether labor productivities in the agricultural
and nonagricultural sectors have converged by using the 5-year average panel
dataset. We have found robust evidence that nonagricultural labor productivity and
agricultural labor productivity did not converge; the former has grown faster and
the gap has increased significantly over time.
We have also observed that within Asia (i) agricultural labor productivity has
converged across economies, (ii) nonagricultural labor productivity has converged
across economies, and (iii) the convergence effect is stronger for the nonagricultural
sector. Agricultural labor productivity growth was found to promote nonagricultural
productivity growth with some lag. That is, despite the slower growth in agricultural
labor productivity, the agricultural sector played an important role in promoting
nonagricultural labor productivity and thus in nonagricultural growth. As we used
the 5-year average panel data, we can identify the middle- to long-term effects by
controlling for short-term fluctuations.
In the second part of the study, we examined whether the labor productivity
gap between the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors reduced poverty,
inequality, and the sectoral population shares over time. While the results vary
depending on the specifications, we have found some evidence that the labor
productivity gap reduces both urban and rural poverty over time as well as national-
level inequality. The gap also increases the share of the population in the urban
sector.
Our results provide the following policy implications. While improvement
in agricultural labor productivity also brings about improvement in nonagricultural
labor productivity, the latter has increased faster than the former over time, resulting
in a gap between the two sectors. The widening gap was found to reduce poverty
and inequality. These results are important in light of the literature on structural
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
134 Asian Development Review
transformation in Asia (e.g., Reardon and Timmer 2014; Imai, Gaiha, and Bresciani
2016), which underscores diffusion from the agricultural sector. Our results suggest
that as the agricultural sector experiences structural changes, it plays a central role
in improving nonagricultural labor productivity and reducing poverty and inequality
within an economy. Policy makers need to facilitate the process of structural
transformation (e.g., commercialization and product diversification of agriculture;
revolutions in supply chain and retail networks; and integration of labor, land, and
credit markets) to improve agricultural labor productivity and reduce poverty and
inequality.
References
Barrett, Christopher B., Luc Christiaensen, Megan Sheahan, and Abebe Shimeles. 2017. “On the
Structural Transformation of Rural Africa.” Journal of African Economies 26 (suppl_1):
i11–i35.
Barro–Lee Educational Attainment Dataset. http://www.barrolee.com/.
Barro, Robert J. 1991. “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries.” The Quarterly Journal
of Economics 106 (2): 407–43.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1992. “Convergence.” Journal of Political Economy
100 (2): 223–51.
Barro, Robert J., Xavier Sala-i-Martin, Olivier Jean Blanchard, and Robert E. Hall. 1991.
“Convergence across States and Regions.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1: 107–
82.
Baumol, William. J., Richard R. Nelson, and Edward N. Wolff, eds. 1994. Convergence
of Productivity: Cross-National Studies and Historical Evidence. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Ben-David, Dan. 1996. “Trade and Convergence among Economies.” Journal of International
Economics 40 (3–4): 279–98.
Bernard, Andrew B., and Charles I. Jones. 1996. “Comparing Apples to Oranges: Productivity
Convergence and Measurement across Industries and Economies.” American Economic
Review 86 (5): 1216–38.
Blundell, Richard, and Stephen Bond. 1998. “Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in
Dynamic Panel Data Models.” Journal of Econometrics 87 (1): 115–43.
Bourguignon, François. 1990. “Growth and Inequality in the Dual Model of Development: The
Role of Demand Factors.” The Review of Economic Studies 57 (2): 215–28.
Bourguignon, Francois, and Christian Morrisson. 1998. “Inequality and Development: The Role
of Dualism.” Journal of Development Economics 57 (2): 233–57.
Choo, Hakchung. 1991. Making Economies More Efficient and More Equitable: Factors
Determining Income Distribution, edited by Toshiyuki Mizoguchi, Noriyuki Takayama,
Masaaki Kuboniwa, and Tsuyoshi Tsuru, 3–24. Tokyo: Kinokuniya and Oxford University
Press.
Christiaensen, Luc, Lionel Demery, and Jesper Kuhl. 2011. “The (Evolving) Role of Agriculture
in Poverty Reduction—An Empirical Perspective.” Journal of Development Economics 96
(2): 239–54.
Dawe, David. 2015. “Agricultural Transformation of Middle-Income Asian Economies:
Diversification, Farm Size, and Mechanization.” FAO ESA Working Paper 15-04.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3
Labor Productivity Gap, and Poverty and Inequality Reduction 135
Dixit, Avinash K. 1973. “Models of Dual Economies.” In Models of Economic Growth, edited by
James A. Mirrlees and Nicholas H. Stern, 325–52. New York: Wiley.
Fields, Gary S. 1993. “Inequality in Dual Economy Models.” The Economic Journal 103 (420):
1228–35.
Ghosh, Madhusudan. 2006. “Regional Convergence in Indian Agriculture.” Indian Journal of
Agricultural Economics 61 (4): 610–29.
Gollin, Douglas, David Lagakos, and Michael E. Waugh. 2013. “The Agricultural Productivity
Gap.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (2): 939–93.
Imai, Katsushi S., Wenya Cheng, and Raghav Gaiha. 2017. “Dynamic and Long-Term Linkages
among Agricultural and Non-Agricultural Growth, Inequality, and Poverty in Developing
Countries.” International Review of Applied Economics 31 (3): 318–38.
Imai, Katsushi S., Raghav Gaiha, and Fabrizio Bresciani. 2016. “Dynamics of Rural
Transformation and Poverty in Rural Asia and the Pacific.” Kobe University RIEB
Discussion Paper DP2016-30.
Imai, Katsushi S., Raghav Gaiha, and Alessandra Garbero. 2017. “Poverty Reduction during
than
is Still More Important
the Rural–Urban Transformation: Rural Development
Urbanisation.” Journal of Policy Modeling 39 (6): 963–82.
Kuznets, Simon Smith. 1971. Economic Growth of Nations: Total Output and Production
Structure. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Levine, Ross, and David Renelt. 1992. “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Economy Growth
Regressions.” American Economic Review 82 (4): 942–63.
Lewis, W. Arthur. 1954. “Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor.” The
Manchester School 22 (2): 139–91.
_____. 1955. The Theory of Economic Growth. Homewood: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.
_____. 1979. “The Dual Economy Revisited.” The Manchester School 47 (3): 211–29.
Martin, Will, and Devashish Mitra. 2001. “Productivity Growth and Convergence in Agriculture
versus Manufacturing.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 49 (2): 403–22.
Moriguchi, Chiaki, and Emmanuel Saez. 2008. “The Evolution of Income Concentration in Japan,
1886–2005: Evidence from Income Tax Statistics.” The Review of Economics and Statistics
90 (4): 713–34.
Mundlak, Yair. 2000. Agriculture and Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Quah, Danny, T. 1996. “Empirics for Economic Growth and Convergence.” European Economic
Review 40 (6): 1353–75.
Ravallion, Martin, and Gaurav Datt. 1996. “How Important to India’s Poor is the Sectoral
Composition of Economic Growth?” The World Bank Economic Review 10 (1): 1–25.
Reardon, Thomas, and C. Peter Timmer. 2014. “Five Inter-Linked Transformations in the Asian
Agrifood Economy: Food Security Implications.” Global Food Security 3 (2): 108–17.
Remans, Roseline, Stephen A. Wood, Nilanjana Saha, Tal Lee Anderman, and Ruth S. DeFries.
2014. “Measuring Nutritional Diversity of National Food Supplies.” Global Food Security
3 (3–4): 174–82.
Robinson, Sherman. 1976. “A Note on the U Hypothesis Relating Income Inequality and
Economic Development.” American Economic Review 66 (3): 437–40.
Vollrath, Dietrich. 2009. “The Dual Economy in Long-Run Development.” Journal of Economic
Growth 14 (4): 287–312.
World Bank. 2016. World Development Indicators 2016. https://openknowledge.worldbank
.org/handle/10986/23969.
l
D
o
w
n
o
a
d
e
d
f
r
o
m
h
t
t
p
:
/
/
d
i
r
e
c
t
.
m
i
t
.
/
e
d
u
a
d
e
v
/
a
r
t
i
c
e
-
p
d
l
f
/
/
/
/
3
6
1
1
1
2
1
6
4
4
1
6
7
a
d
e
v
_
a
_
0
0
1
2
5
p
d
/
.
f
b
y
g
u
e
s
t
t
o
n
0
8
S
e
p
e
m
b
e
r
2
0
2
3